PPE Capstone: New Deal Politics
Spring 2020
Required Reading Commentaries
You are required to write four commentaries on the course readings, submitting one per week for weeks 2-5 based on a date schedule that is provided below (see the end of the assignment). Your commentaries must be submitted on Canvas on the dates indicated on the schedule. Late commentaries will not be accepted.
Your commentaries should meet three goals: 1) give a summary of the key point(s) made in the course reading you are writing about based on your understanding; 2) provide some examples of the evidence used in the reading (possibly including direct quotes) to show how the author supports the key point(s); 3) devote at least two concluding paragraphs to connecting this reading to another class reading (this can be a reading from earlier in the quarter, or another reading assigned on the same date in cases where I have assigned more than one reading).
Part 1: Identify the key point or points in the reading. What is the main argument or key insight you see emerging from this reading? Can you give a quote from the text that supports your understanding of the reading?
Part 2: Identify at least two pieces of “evidence” that the author uses to support the main argument or key point of the reading. In the readings for this class, evidence will often be in the form of specific historical examples that support the larger claim. You should discuss some details from these examples to show how the author makes the point (again, direct quotes are fine, but you should also put some of this into your own words).
For instance, if a reading makes the argument that the declining political power of business interests was an important reason that the New Deal welfare state emerged, the author may then go on to support this point by showing how business interests tried to oppose Social Security, and yet it still passed despite this business opposition.
Also be sensitive to nuance in the author’s analysis, and try to point this out in your commentary. For example, perhaps the author argues that Social Security passed despite business opposition, but then goes on to acknowledge that business interests were able to modify Social Security afterwards in ways that suited their needs (so some business power was still relevant to what happened in the New Deal, even if not dominant).
Part 3: Conclude your commentary by thinking about what this reading adds to other readings in this class. This can include making some comparison with the other reading assigned on that same date in cases where I assign two readings. For example, perhaps you are writing on a reading that describes the positive accomplishments of the New Deal in relation to African Americans, and you want to consider how this fits with the other reading from that day that highlights how the New Deal actually perpetuated racial inequality. Or maybe the specific topic discussed by the reading fleshes out and supports an insight from an earlier reading, and you want to make note of that connection and explore its significance.
Format:
Each commentary must be typed and 2-3 pages in length. The goal is to be concise, but also to give enough details to show a clear understanding and engagement with the reading. Commentaries should be double-spaced, 12-point font, 1” margins. To effectively summarize the reading, you must cite relevant pages in parentheses within your text. Commentaries will be uploaded to Canvas on the Assignments page (this will be set up this week).
You are required to include page citations for paraphrased summaries, not just direct quotes. For these commentaries you do not need to include the author name in the citation, since it should already be clear that you are citing the text under review. Your commentaries must also be clearly presented and well organized. If you do not meet these format goals, I will return the commentary to you for revision before I accept it.
Overall, the commentaries are 15% of your grade (150 points). Each commentary will be assigned 1-40 points, based on both content and presentation (so if you do these exceptionally well you can actually earn some bonus points). If you are unhappy with your grade on a specific commentary, I will accept one revised commentary, due by the end of the 7th week of the quarter, which will replace the grade on the original commentary. That would mean, for instance, that if you have to miss submitting one on the schedule below you would get a 0, but then you could replace it by turning in the one you missed as a ‘revised’ commentary in week 7).
Schedule:
Group A: Sean Arent, Jinling Chen, Cody Dunagan, Rich Graham, Leanne Li, Pinedo Liberato, Tim Nunes, Dylan Ost, Jiachen Shen, Linjie Wang.
Group B: Carlos Brambila, Liansheng Cui, Sim Garcha, Sam Knight, Zhikun Li, Jaden Moon, Mike Olson, Robert Robinson, Mario Utica, Esperanza Williams.
Group A
|
Group B |
Week 2: Monday, April 6 (by the end of the day)
Pick one of the assigned chapters from Rauchway, Great Depression and New Deal (Chap. 4-7)
|
Week 2: Wednesday, April 8 (by the end of the day)
Skocpol and Finegold, “State Capacity and Economic Intervention in the Early New Deal” |
Group A
|
Group B |
Week 3: Monday, April 13
Sidney Milkis, ““Franklin D. Roosevelt, the Economic Constitutional Order and the New Politics of Presidential Leadership”
|
Week 3: Wednesday, April 15
Hacker and Pierson, “Business Power and Social Policy: Employers and the Formation of the American Welfare State" |
Week 4: Wednesday, April 22
Neil Maher, “A New Deal Body Politic: Landscape, Labor, and the Civilians Conservation Corps" or Charles Williams, “Reconsidering CIO Political Culture: Briggs Local 212 and the Sources of Militancy in the Early UAW”
|
Week 4: Wednesday, April 22
Neil Maher, “A New Deal Body Politic: Landscape, Labor, and the Civilians Conservation Corps" or Charles Williams, “Reconsidering CIO Political Culture: Briggs Local 212 and the Sources of Militancy in the Early UAW”
|
Week 5: Monday, April 27
H. Sitkoff, “The Start of a New Deal” or Ira Katznelson, “Welfare in Black and White”
|
Week 5: Wednesday, April 29
S. Ware, “Women and the New Deal” or Suzanne Mettler, “Social Citizens of Separate Sovereignties”
|
The Great Depression and the New Deal:
A Very Short Introduction
Very Short Introductions available now:
AFRICAN HISTORY John Parker and Richard Rathbone
AMERICAN POLITICAL PARTIES AND ELECTIONS L. Sandy Maisel
THE AMERICAN PRESIDENCY Charles O. Jones
ANARCHISM Colin Ward ANCIENT EGYPT Ian Shaw ANCIENT PHILOSOPHY Julia Annas ANCIENT WARFARE
Harry Sidebottom
ANGLICANISM Mark Chapman THE ANGLO-SAXON AGE John Blair ANIMAL RIGHTS David DeGrazia ANTISEMITISM Steven Beller ARCHAEOLOGY Paul Bahn ARCHITECTURE Andrew Ballantyne ARISTOTLE Jonathan Barnes ART HISTORY Dana Arnold ART THEORY Cynthia Freeland THE HISTORY OF
ASTRONOMY Michael Hoskin ATHEISM Julian Baggini AUGUSTINE Henry Chadwick BARTHES Jonathan Culler BESTSELLERS John Sutherland THE BIBLE John Riches THE BRAIN Michael O’Shea BRITISH POLITICS Anthony Wright BUDDHA Michael Carrithers BUDDHISM Damien Keown BUDDHIST ETHICS Damien Keown CAPITALISM James Fulcher THE CELTS Barry Cunliffe CHAOS Leonard Smith CHOICE THEORY Michael Allingham CHRISTIAN ART Beth Williamson
CHRISTIANITY Linda Woodhead CLASSICS
Mary Beard and John Henderson
CLASSICAL MYTHOLOGY Helen Morales
CLAUSEWITZ Michael Howard THE COLD WAR Robert McMahon CONSCIOUSNESS Susan Blackmore CONTEMPORARY ART
Julian Stallabrass
CONTINENTAL PHILOSOPHY Simon Critchley
COSMOLOGY Peter Coles THE CRUSADES Christopher Tyerman CRYPTOGRAPHY
Fred Piper and Sean Murphy
DADA AND SURREALISM David Hopkins
DARWIN Jonathan Howard THE DEAD SEA SCROLLS Timothy Lim DEMOCRACY Bernard Crick DESCARTES Tom Sorell DESIGN John Heskett DINOSAURS David Norman DOCUMENTARY FILM
Patricia Aufderheide
DREAMING J. Allan Hobson DRUGS Leslie Iversen THE EARTH Martin Redfern ECONOMICS Partha Dasgupta EGYPTIAN MYTH Geraldine Pinch EIGHTEENTH-CENTURY
BRITAIN Paul Langford THE ELEMENTS Philip Ball EMOTION Dylan Evans EMPIRE Stephen Howe ENGELS Terrell Carver
VERY SHORT INTRODUCTIONS are for anyone wanting a stimulating and accessible way in to a new subject. They are written by experts, and
have been published in more than 25 languages worldwide.
The series began in 1995, and now represents a wide variety of topics in
history, philosophy, religion, science, and the humanities. Over the next few
years it will grow to a library of around 200 volumes — a Very Short
Introduction to everything from ancient Egypt and Indian philosophy to
conceptual art and cosmology.
ETHICS Simon Blackburn THE EUROPEAN UNION
John Pinder and Simon Usherwood
EVOLUTION Brian and Deborah Charlesworth
EXISTENTIALISM Thomas Flynn FASCISM Kevin Passmore FEMINISM Margaret Walters THE FIRST WORLD WAR
Michael Howard
FOSSILS Keith Thomson FOUCAULT Gary Gutting THE FRENCH REVOLUTION
William Doyle
FREE WILL Thomas Pink FREUD Anthony Storr FUNDAMENTALISM Malise Ruthven GALILEO Stillman Drake GAME THEORY Ken Binmore GANDHI Bhikhu Parekh GEOPOLITICS Klaus Dodds GERMAN LITERATURE Nicholas Boyle GLOBAL CATASTROPHES Bill McGuire GLOBALIZATION Manfred Steger GLOBAL WARMING Mark Maslin THE GREAT DEPRESSION AND THE
NEW DEAL Eric Rauchway HABERMAS James Gordon Finlayson HEGEL Peter Singer HEIDEGGER Michael Inwood HIEROGLYPHS Penelope Wilson HINDUISM Kim Knott HISTORY John H. Arnold HIV/AIDS Alan Whiteside HOBBES Richard Tuck HUMAN EVOLUTION Bernard Wood HUMAN RIGHTS Andrew Clapham HUME A. J. Ayer IDEOLOGY Michael Freeden INDIAN PHILOSOPHY Sue Hamilton INTELLIGENCE Ian J. Deary INTERNATIONAL
MIGRATION Khalid Koser INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS
Paul Wilkinson
ISLAM Malise Ruthven JOURNALISM Ian Hargreaves JUDAISM Norman Solomon JUNG Anthony Stevens KABBALAH Joseph Dan KAFKA Ritchie Robertson KANT Roger Scruton KIERKEGAARD Patrick Gardiner
THE KORAN Michael Cook LINGUISTICS Peter Matthews LITERARY THEORY Jonathan Culler LOCKE John Dunn LOGIC Graham Priest MACHIAVELLI Quentin Skinner THE MARQUIS DE SADE John Phillips MARX Peter Singer MATHEMATICS Timothy Gowers MEDICAL ETHICS Tony Hope MEDIEVAL BRITAIN
John Gillingham and Ralph A. Griffiths
MODERN ART David Cottington MODERN CHINA Rana Mitter MODERN IRELAND Senia Pašeta MOLECULES Philip Ball MUSIC Nicholas Cook MYTH Robert A. Segal NATIONALISM Steven Grosby THE NEW TESTAMENT AS
LITERATURE Kyle Keefer NEWTON Robert Iliffe NIETZSCHE Michael Tanner NINETEENTH-CENTURY
BRITAIN Christopher Harvie and H. C. G. Matthew
NORTHERNIRELAND MarcMulholland THE OLD TESTAMENT
Michael D. Coogan
PARTICLE PHYSICS Frank Close PAUL E. P. Sanders PHILOSOPHY Edward Craig PHILOSOPHYOF LAW RaymondWacks PHILOSOPHY OF SCIENCE
Samir Okasha
PHOTOGRAPHY Steve Edwards PLATO Julia Annas POLITICS Kenneth Minogue POLITICAL PHILOSOPHY David Miller POSTCOLONIALISM Robert Young POSTMODERNISM Christopher Butler POSTSTRUCTURALISM
Catherine Belsey
PREHISTORY Chris Gosden PRESOCRATIC PHILOSOPHY
Catherine Osborne
PSYCHOLOGY Gillian Butler and Freda McManus
PSYCHIATRY Tom Burns THE QUAKERS Pink Dandelion QUANTUM THEORY
John Polkinghorne
RACISM Ali Rattansi
THE RENAISSANCE Jerry Brotton RENAISSANCE ART
Geraldine A. Johnson
ROMAN BRITAIN Peter Salway THE ROMAN EMPIRE
Christopher Kelly
ROUSSEAU Robert Wokler RUSSELL A. C. Grayling RUSSIAN LITERATURE Catriona Kelly THE RUSSIAN REVOLUTION
S. A. Smith
SCHIZOPHRENIA Chris Frith and Eve Johnstone
SCHOPENHAUER Christopher Janaway
SHAKESPEARE Germaine Greer SIKHISM Eleanor Nesbitt SOCIAL AND CULTURAL
ANTHROPOLOGY John Monaghan and Peter Just
SOCIALISM Michael Newman SOCIOLOGY Steve Bruce SOCRATES C. C. W. Taylor THE SPANISH CIVIL WAR
Helen Graham
SPINOZA Roger Scruton STUART BRITAIN John Morrill TERRORISM Charles Townshend THEOLOGY David F. Ford THE HISTORY OF TIME
Leofranc Holford-Strevens
TRAGEDY Adrian Poole THE TUDORS John Guy TWENTIETH-CENTURY
BRITAIN Kenneth O. Morgan THE VIKINGS Julian Richards WITTGENSTEIN A. C. Grayling WORLD MUSIC Philip Bohlman THE WORLD TRADE
ORGANIZATION Amrita Narlikar
Available soon:
1066 George Garnett
Expressionism Katerina Reed-Tsocha
Galaxies John Gribbin Geography
John Matthews and David Herbert
History of Life Michael Benton
History of Medicine William Bynum
Law Raymond Wacks The Meaning of Life
Terry Eagleton
Memory Jonathan Foster
Mormonism Richard Lyman Bushman
Nelson Mandela Elleke Boehmer
Nuclear Weapons Joseph M. Siracusa
Religion in America Timothy Beal
Science and Religion Thomas Dixon
Sexuality Véronique Mottier
The United Nations Jussi M. Hanhimäki
The Vietnam War Mark Atwood Lawrence
For more information visit our web site www.oup.co.uk/general/vsi/
Eric Rauchway
The Great Depression &
the New Deal A Very Short Introduction
1
3 Oxford University Press, Inc., publishes works that further
Oxford University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education.
Oxford New York Auckland Cape Town Dar es Salaam Hong Kong Karachi Kuala Lumpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico City Nairobi
New Delhi Shanghai Taipei Toronto
With offices in Argentina Austria Brazil Chile Czech Republic France Greece Guatemala Hungary Italy Japan Poland Portugal Singapore South Korea Switzerland Thailand Turkey Ukraine Vietnam
Copyright � 2008 by Oxford University Press, Inc.
Published by Oxford University Press, Inc. 198 Madison Avenue, New York, NY 10016
www.oup.com
Oxford is a registered trademark of Oxford University Press
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means,
electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior permission of Oxford University Press.
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Rauchway, Eric.
The Great Depression and the New Deal : a very short introduction / Eric Rauchway.
p. cm.— (Very short introductions ; 166) Includes bibliographical references and index.
ISBN 978–0–19–532634–5 (pbk.) 1. United States—History—1919–1933. 2. United States—History—1933–1945.
3. Depressions—1929—United States. 4. New Deal, 1933–1939. 5. United States—Economic conditions—1918–1945. 6. United States—Social conditions—1933–1945.
7. Roosevelt, Franklin D. (Franklin Delano), 1882–1945. 8. Depressions—1929—Europe.
9. Europe—Economic conditions—1918–1945. I. Title. E806.R38 2008 973.91—dc22 2007030523
1 3 5 7 9 8 6 4 2
Printed in the United States of America on acid-free paper
Contents
Acknowledgments viii
List of Illustrations ix
Introduction 1
1 The World in Debt 8
2 The Hoover Years 23
3 Americans in the Depression 38
4 Reflation and Relief 56
5 Managing Farm and Factory 72
6 Countervailing Power 87
7 The End of the Beginning 105
Conclusion 126
Further Reading 134
Table 1. Major federal acts of the Great Depression
and New Deal 137
Index 143
Acknowledgments
I owe most to scholars cited in the text and am additionally grateful
to Alan Brinkley, Greg Clark, Andrew Cohen, Meg Jacobs, Ari
Kelman, David Kennedy, Peter Lindert, Alan Olmstead, Kathy
Olmsted, Steve Sheffrin, Alan M. Taylor, Louis Warren,
undergraduates enrolled in History 174B at UC Davis in Spring
2007, and the conscientious referees and staff of the press for
valuable comments and conversations about the Great Depression
and New Deal.
List of Illustrations
1 Breadline in New
York City 41
Franklin D. Roosevelt
Library
2 Hooverville squatters’
shacks 45
Library of Congress,
LC-USF34-004976-E
3 GDP and Unemployment 55
Historical Statistics of the
United States, series Ba475
(unemployment) and Ca9
(GDP).
4 Franklin D. Roosevelt during
a ‘‘Fireside Chat’’ 58
Library of Congress,
LC-USZ62-118215
5 Civilian Conservation Corps
poultry farm 79
Franklin D. Roosevelt
Library
6 Civilian Conservation Corps
weeding a Tennessee Valley
Authority nursery 90
Library of Congress,
LC-USW3-004511-D
7 Social Security Act 98
Franklin D. Roosevelt
Library
8 ‘‘White Trade Only’’ 107
Library of Congress, LC-
USF33- 006392-M4
9 Sinclair Lewis’s It Can’t
Happen Here 121
Library of Congress,
LC-USZC2-881
10 WPA Federal Art Project
Mural 122
National Archives and
Records Administration
69-N-P-1304
This page intentionally left blank
Introduction
In 1932 the United States economy stood at its lowest ebb in
modern history. An army of out-of-work military veterans camped
and marched in Washington, DC. Unemployment stood at around
25 percent. Indeed the entire world seemed to have ground to a
halt. Facing this crisis, Franklin D. Roosevelt accepted the
Democratic nomination for president, pledging himself to ‘‘a new
deal for the American people.’’ 1 In that speech alone, elements of
the ‘‘new deal’’ included increasing public works, supporting
agricultural prices, creating new mortgage markets, shortening the
working day and week, regulating securities, restoring
international trade, reforesting the countryside, and repealing
Prohibition. After taking office in 1933, Roosevelt worked with
Congress to get laws passed for all these measures and more: by the
end of the decade, the New Deal had grown to include social
insurance against old age, unemployment, and disability;
watershed management; support for unionization; deposit
insurance; and a strengthened Federal Reserve System, among
other innovations.
The New Deal included a variety of sometimes contradictory
components that scholars still struggle to summarize. Often
historians agree with Isaiah Berlin, who said in 1955 that the New
Deal was an impressive balancing act, able ‘‘to reconcile individual
liberty . . . with the indispensable minimum of organising and
1
authority.’’ 2 But as David M. Kennedy notes, we can see the New
Deal thus only when it is ‘‘illumined by the stern-lantern of
history.’’ 3 Listening to Roosevelt’s pledges in 1932, watching
Congress pour reforms forth in the first one hundred days of his
administration in 1933, seeing the White House reply to challenges
from the Supreme Court and political opponents in 1935, hearing
Roosevelt campaign as ‘‘the master’’ of corporate interests in 1936,
it would have been hard to discern in advance what seemed clear in
the wake of the decade’s passing. And indeed, there is little proof
that Roosevelt or anyone else set out to create the carefully
balanced system that the New Deal became: it evolved as the
president and Congress responded to the judiciary, the electorate,
and the changing world of the Depression.
In this very short introduction to the Great Depression and the
New Deal, I offer some basic ideas for a first understanding of this
profound crisis and America’s still-influential legislative response.
The world that broke down in 1929 broke down for reasons that
astute observers had predicted in advance. The subsequent and
nearly total failure to repair the damage owed to clear errors of
judgment and action, and the prolonged misery that millions of
people suffered could therefore have been lessened. Roosevelt
and the Democratic Congresses of the New Deal era achieved a
marked historical success by correcting those errors. They also
committed errors of their own, and I do not slight them here.
But in the 1936 election, the American voters overwhelmingly
asked their leaders to forge forward with their experiments,
mistakes aside, rather than return to the old and, to their minds,
wholly discredited ways. This spirit of pragmatic experimentation
became the basis for a generation’s faith in the new American
way, not just in the United States but around the world.
Now, if you doubt the story is quite so simple, and if you insist
that these simple statements require qualifications and nuance,
I shall have to concede the point—beyond the confines of this
brief book, I greatly respect the complexity of this era and the
2
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
scholarship covering it. On the principle that you will go on from
here if you wish fully to appreciate the period, the book concludes
with recommendations for further reading. But the body of the
book sticks to these simpler lines of argument on the grounds that
they serve as a useful introduction to the subject.
The Great Depression began in the late 1920s, not necessarily with
the Great Crash of 1929 but around that time, and afflicted a world
tied together by specific kinds of debts, both within and between
countries. Chapter 1 outlines that world and America’s peculiar
place in it, explaining how it differed from the world before World
War I, and emphasizing the vulnerabilities of the system as
outlined by contemporary critics: the web of debt binding that
world together looked fragile to its keenest observers.
Chapter 2 discusses the reactions to the crisis, first of the Federal
Reserve System, which serves the United States as a central bank,
and second of President Herbert Hoover and the Republican
majority in Congress. Contrary to Democratic accusations, the
Republicans did not do nothing—but Hoover’s own principles
prevented him from doing nearly enough, and the crisis worsened
appallingly under his leadership.
Chapter 3 shows that the greatness of the Great Depression owes
to its widespread impact. It afflicted all sections of the American
economy and much of the world. Perhaps most importantly, it
encouraged middle-class American taxpayers and voters to
identify themselves with the unfortunate many, rather the
fortunate few.
The discussion here of the New Deal, like all such discussions,
requires a selective principle to explain what belongs under that
rubric and what does not. You will find two in this book. The first is
chronological. While writers sometimes use the term ‘‘New Deal’’
to refer to the modern Democratic Party’s agenda, or indeed the
expansion of the American state under any administration for any
3
In tro
d u c tio
n
purpose after the Roosevelt era (a concept that sometimes goes
under the name, ‘‘the New Deal order’’), I concern myself in this
book chiefly with the 1930s—after which Roosevelt and his
contemporaries thought the New Deal ended—and look only
briefly to its legacy in the war years. 4 The second is functional. I
divide the New Deal here into three parts: (1) those measures that
appear to have worked to reverse the Depression; (2) those that did
not; and (3) those that had little to do with fighting the current
disaster but served to prevent or soften future ones.
Beyond Roosevelt’s core conviction that ‘‘[n]ecessitous men are
not free men,’’ little held the New Deal together. 5 New Deal
programs embodied no single approach to political management of
the economy. They originated in no single book, speech, or person’s
thoughts. In some instances, Roosevelt himself had little to do
with, or even opposed, ultimately important and successful
legislation. The New Deal emerged over time from the fights
between the president, the Congress, the Supreme Court, all of
them influenced by the electoral returns that time after time
supported this continuing conflict, in the interests of creating a
stronger country.
Chapter 4, ‘‘Reflation and Relief,’’ covers the New Deal
stabilization and shoring-up of America’s banks, currency, and
credit, and the simultaneous effort to supply immediate relief to
the Depression’s suffering millions while still keeping American
traditions and institutions intact. These efforts alone, pursued
vigorously, might eventually have ended the Depression, but New
Dealers had greater ambitions.
Chapter 5, ‘‘Managing Farm and Factory,’’ explains New Deal
attempts to re-create the managed economy of World War I for the
peacetime crisis of the 1930s. These efforts generated controversy
at the time and in retrospect appear considerably ill-advised. But
they had roots deep in American politics, and their failures helped
turn the New Deal into the balanced mechanism it became.
4
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Chapter 6, ‘‘Countervailing Power,’’ considers the ways New
Dealers tried to redistribute influence in the American economy.
They did not use state redistribution of wealth through tax policy
and welfare payments; rather, they used law to encourage interest
groups and individual actors to act independently of their
employers.
By 1936, the use of countervailing power had become a distinctive
hallmark of the New Deal. Never so efficient as direct state action,
the strategy of countervailing power allowed Roosevelt to, in
Berlin’s words, ‘‘establish new rules of social justice . . . without
forcing his country into some doctrinaire strait-jacket, whether of
socialism or State capitalism, or the kind of new social organisation
which the Fascist regimes flaunted as the New Order.’’ 6 By such
methods the New Deal gave weaker groups in society the ability to
negotiate better deals in a marketplace it left substantially intact.
The book’s final chapter shows that the American electorate
ratified Roosevelt in the landslide victory of 1936 and explains why
the New Deal nevertheless ground to a halt within a few years after
that. The Supreme Court played its part, and so did Franklin
Roosevelt’s overreaching ambition. But so too did the results of
their first experiments change some New Dealers’ minds. And
finally, the impending war in Europe and America’s response to it
set aside the New Deal’s fiscal caution and experimental care.
The New Deal did not end the Great Depression. As one American
who lived through the 1930s told Studs Terkel, ‘‘industries needed
to make guns for World War II made that happen.’’ 7
Unemployment did not return to its 1929 level until 1943. 8 But
while we can therefore say that the New Deal did not finish the job,
we cannot say that it was not working. Throughout the 1930s, with
the exception of the recession in 1937–38, the economy was
improving—growing on average 8 percent a year from 1933–37
and 10 percent a year from 1938–41, while unemployment fell
steadily as well. 9 This impressive rate of recovery reminds us how
5
In tro
d u c tio
n
far the United States had to go to recover from the Hoover era. It
also helps explain why the New Deal achieved such political
success.
As a program to reform the American and global political
economy, the New Deal met with more ambiguous fortune because
it blurred into the war. The New Deal started and mainly stayed a
purely American set of solutions to a problem of global
importance, although the Anglo-American trade agreement of
1938 pointed toward an international method of reviving the world
economy. And while the postwar order that Roosevelt in his last
years helped secure for the world owed much to New Deal methods
of pragmatic experimentation and shifting power away from states,
because the war began before the lessons of the New Deal had
made themselves quite clear, observers could not readily
disentangle the two great events. The moral clarity of the 1940s
obscured the hard choices, partial successes, and political bargains
of the 1930s.
In the conclusion I discuss the New Deal’s influence on the postwar
world through the Bretton Woods system of international
agreements for economic stability, which endured until the 1970s.
Not until then did the United States begin to retreat from its New
Deal at home and abroad. And even after several subsequent
decades during which politicians have led a revival in America’s
pre-1929 beliefs, claiming repeatedly that government is a
problem, not a solution, for modern economies, the New Deal’s
basic commitment to shared responsibility for economic security
and its skepticism toward the complete reliability of bankers,
brokers, and corporate executives has not quite died.
Throughout this book, the reader will find these interpretations
guided not only by the easier wisdom of scholarly hindsight, but
also by the perceptive assessments of contemporary observers. Just
as Americans enjoyed the great good fortune of Franklin
Roosevelt’s unique presidential competence in both peace and war,
6
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
they had also among them a remarkable generation of social
scientists and other political analysts. The book relies on them as
much as on those who have followed them and profited from their
vision. And on the advice of one of the most acute among them, we
begin with a description of the world that came limping to a halt in
the Great War of 1914–18.
Notes
1. ‘‘Text of Governor Roosevelt’s Speech at the Convention Accepting
the Nomination,’’ New York Times, January 3, 1932, 8.
2. Isaiah Berlin, ‘‘President Franklin Delano Roosevelt,’’ in The Proper
Study of Mankind: An Anthology of Essays, ed. Henry Hardy and
Roger Hausheer (London: Chatto and Windus, 1997), 636–37.
3. David M. Kennedy, Freedom from Fear: The American People in
Depression and War, 1929–1945 (New York: Oxford University
Press, 1999), 365.
4. Steve Fraser and Gary Gerstle, eds., The Rise and Fall of the New
Deal Order, 1930–1980 (Princeton: Princeton University Press,
1989). On the New Deal’s contribution to the later growth of the
executive branch, see Theodore Lowi, The End of Liberalism: The
Second Republic of the United States (New York: W. W. Norton,
1979).
5. Cited in Kennedy, Freedom from Fear, 280. See also Berlin,
‘‘President Franklin Delano Roosevelt.’’
6. Berlin, ‘‘President Franklin Delano Roosevelt,’’ 629–30.
7. Studs Terkel, Hard Times: An Oral History of the Great Depression
(New York: The New Press, 2000), 57.
8. Susan B. Carter et al., eds., Historical Statistics of the United States,
Earliest Times to the Present, Millennial Edition (New York:
Cambridge University Press, 2006), series Ba475. Unemployment
as a percentage of the civilian labor force was 2.9 percent in 1929;
3.1 percent in 1942 and 1.8 percent in 1943.
9. Christina D. Romer, ‘‘What Ended the Great Depression?,’’ Journal
of Economic History 52, no. 4 (1992): 757.
7
In tro
d u c tio
n
Chapter 1
The World in Debt
However various the explanations for the Great Depression have
grown, they share an understanding that the world wracked by the
crisis of the late 1920s differed significantly from the world in
which most people had grown up. Inasmuch as the world had a
single, integrated economy, it had recently undergone profound
changes as a result of World War I. The war made it harder for
people, goods, and money to move around the globe, and it shifted
the direction in which they flowed, too. Putting the United States
at the center of this new system, the war also changed America,
rendering the once-peripheral New World nation’s peculiarities
central to the planet’s concerns. Nor do these events and their
potential for disaster appear only in retrospective clarity—some
observers saw them coming.
Looking forward from the Treaty of Versailles at 1919, the
economist John Maynard Keynes forecast what lay in wait for the
industrial world: ‘‘depression of the standard of life of the
European populations to a point which will mean actual starvation
for some (a point already reached in Russia and approximately
reached in Austria). Men . . . in their distress may overturn the
remnants of organisation, and submerge civilisation itself in their
attempts to satisfy desperately the overwhelming needs of the
individual.’’ 1 Depression, desperation, and the dismantling of
civilization would result, Keynes wrote, from ‘‘the economic
8
consequences of the peace,’’ and although Keynes, perhaps
mistakenly, attributed this impending disaster partly to the treaty’s
provisions, he also criticized its omissions. 2 World leaders at
Versailles might have restored and codified the global system
that prevailed from about 1870 to 1914, a system Keynes described
as an ‘‘economic Utopia.’’ But they missed this chance, producing
instead a world quite unlike Utopia. 3
Before 1914, people, goods, and capital crossed national borders
with relative impunity. In consequence, they had the greatest
possible scope to seek a place where their work would yield the
greatest possible profit. To a considerable extent, this movement
across borders meant the export of excess from industrial Europe.
Between the middle of the nineteenth century and World War I,
about fifty-five million people left Europe to find their fortune
in New World nations. Mostly industrial workers looking for
higher wages in a worldwide market for their labor, their departure
from Europe decreased the supply of workers there, raising wages
for the laborers they left behind. Their arrival in the land-rich
nations of the New World helped push development out into
the frontiers. This migration did not occur altogether without
hindrance. To describe the international markets of the nineteenth
century as truly global represents some exaggeration, in large
measure because New World nations preferred some parts of
the globe over others when forging a cross-border market in, for
example, labor. Notably, in the 1850s Australian states
began limiting Chinese immigration, and by the early twentieth
century the United States, Canada, and Australia all had
erected high hurdles to immigration from both China and Japan;
the United States in 1917 not only added a ‘‘barred zone’’ that
blocked almost all the rest of Asia but also adopted a literacy test
to reduce the number of incoming people. Nevertheless,
these restrictions let millions of immigrants, particularly from
southern and eastern Europe, move to better employment in the
New World.
9
T h e W
o rld
in D e b t
During the same period, the British empire generally backed the
free movement of goods across borders. The relatively untaxed
passage of things in trade—raw materials and finished products
alike—between the Old World and the New allowed each nation to
produce mainly what it was best suited to make. Although
countries of the era sometimes raised barriers to trade as they did
to migration—Latin American countries had especially high
tariffs—international trade moved with relative freedom,
especially compared to the 1920s, and Britain led in the promotion
of lower tariffs. 4
Observers noted that trade with Britain proved especially useful to
many developing countries. British banks backed the builders of
roads, canals, and railways as these countries stretched into their
hinterlands and prairies. Bringing the fields under tillage made the
New World more productive, and selling products back to their
lender, Britain, helped developing countries defray their debts.
Combined with the movement of goods and people, the movement
of capital created a virtuous circle, at least so far as Europe was
concerned. As a British economist wrote in 1909, ‘‘by the
investment of capital in other lands we have, first, provided the
borrowing countries with the credit which gave them the power to
purchase the goods needed for their development, and secondly,
enabled them to increase their own productions so largely that they
have been able to pay us the interest and profits upon our capital
and also to purchase greatly increased quantities of British goods.’’ 5
Keynes regarded this vanished system so highly because it had
allowed Europe for the first time to relieve the pressure that an
increase of population had appeared inexorably to put on the
supply of food. Keynes explained: ‘‘With the growth of the
European population there were more emigrants on the one hand
to till the soil of the new countries, and, on the other, more
workmen were available in Europe to prepare the industrial
products and capital goods which were to maintain the emigrant
populations in their new homes, and to build the railways and
10
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
ships which were to make accessible to Europe food and raw
products from distant sources.’’ 6 The war shut down this system.
People and goods could no longer move freely, and their formerly
productive power went instead toward destruction. Capital funded
the war’s western front instead of the New World frontier. But
worse, once the war ended, the peace did nothing to restore the lost
world. ‘‘The Treaty includes no provisions for the economic
rehabilitation of Europe . . . or to adjust the systems of the Old
World and the New,’’ Keynes complained. 7
Looking back from the 1930s, the British historian E. H. Carr
wrote, ‘‘In 1918 world leadership was offered, by almost unanimous
consent, to the United States . . . it was then declined.’’ 8 Most
notably, the United States declined to lead the world in
reconstructing the old, open economy. Indeed, it moved in the
opposite direction.
The United States had tried to limit immigration before the war,
but it turned to the task with greater energy and effectiveness in
the 1920s. Congress established quota limits on immigration with
the laws of 1921 and 1924. Other New World countries blocked
immigration in their own ways. Some joined the United States in
barring political radicals and classes of the criminal, poor, or
disabled. Brazilians tried to steer immigration to farms, rather
than cities. Canada’s 1919 immigration act allowed officials to bar
‘‘immigrants . . . deemed unsuitable owing to their peculiar
customs, habits, [and] modes of life.’’ 9 These restrictions made it
harder for Europeans to find opportunities overseas, as Keynes had
foreseen in 1919.
The movement in goods slowed owing to restrictive law as
well. The United States raised tariffs in 1921 and 1922, and
other countries began following suit. Alarmed diplomats
convened conferences whose delegates advocated lifting these
barriers, culminating with the League of Nations’ World Economic
Conference in 1927, which declared itself strongly against tariffs, to
11
T h e W
o rld
in D e b t
no effect. The Americans had a history of high tariffs stretching
through the nineteenth century, but as the New York Times noted
in 1926, circumstances had changed since then: ‘‘It needs no
political economist to see that our situation in the world of trade
has been radically altered by the events following 1914. A fiscal
policy which might have been defensible before that year has since
gone hopelessly awry. Our immense and increasing investments
abroad cannot indefinitely be paid for unless we are willing to take
what our foreign debtors can offer us.’’ 10
With the war the United States had switched positions, almost
overnight, from the world’s great debtor to the world’s great
creditor. New York replaced London as the central lender in the
world’s credit network. This move meant more than merely a shift
in position and priority. Postwar debts differed from prewar
borrowing. New World borrowers spent nineteenth-century
British loans on railroads and ranches, building the capacity to
repay their lenders. Belligerent borrowers spent wartime American
loans on shot and shell, destroying that capacity. Nations wounded
in war borrowed more money to repay their debts, sometimes
borrowing from America to pay other belligerents who in turn paid
America.
This new global system of the 1920s, less open and flexible than its
predecessor, relied on continued American lending to fund deficits
and debts around the war-impoverished world. And for a time,
American lending served this purpose. Then, in 1928, it all but
stopped, sending Germany, Poland, Brazil, Argentina, Australia,
and Canada into recession. 11 But Americans were not looking at
the limping world. They had their eyes on the racing economy at
home.
After the United States recovered from a postwar recession in 1921,
its economy grew at a healthy annual rate. American workers
produced more goods more efficiently, and their incomes
increased, if not quite so quickly as the profits born from their
12
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
greater productivity. 12
Many Americans’ optimism grew, too: they
thought they had entered a new era of prosperity, when more
Americans could afford more luxury goods and live, at least
materially, better lives than ever before. So securely did they hold
this belief that they accepted newly available offers of credit in
order to buy what they could not afford from their own pockets. By
the end of the decade Americans were living lives well-furnished
with debt.
Before World War I, the average American household went a little
more into debt each year—maybe a $4 increase over the year
before, excluding mortgages. In the 1920s, the average increase
more than tripled to about $14 a year. 13 With that borrowed money
Americans bought the same goods they were increasingly making:
expensive, durable, luxury items that gave them more varied
amusements and higher expectations from life. The 1920s brought
regular radio programs, and Americans bought radio sets and
phonographs. They bought household appliances, like electric
refrigerators. Most visibly, they bought cars. 14
The production, purchase, and financing of automobiles drove the
perception and reality of American prosperity in the 1920s. The
output of America’s automobile factories more than doubled over
the decade, so that by 1929 the 4.4 million cars they produced were
the single most valuable chunk of U.S. manufacturing output. At
decade’s end about 447,000 people worked in the automotive
industry—only slightly fewer than worked in iron and steel, the
nation’s biggest manufacturing industry. The more cars Americans
made, the more they drove up demand for glass, rubber, steel, and
petroleum. Car-buyers drove the growth of roads, suburban
houses, shopping centers, and other roadside attractions. 15
In 1920 American motor vehicle bureaus recorded only one car
registered for every three households; by the end of the decade the
country had a car for almost every household. In 1929 there were
about 23 million cars for a nation of about 123 million people: at a
13
T h e W
o rld
in D e b t
cozy fit of six per car, the whole country could have gone on the
road at once. 16
Henry Ford’s motor company provided some of the technical and
business innovations that made these changes possible. By World
War I, Ford had settled on the Model T as its all-purpose consumer
model, developed the moving assembly line as a method of mass
production, and began touting the high wages its workers earned,
as a way of ensuring their loyalty and their ability to purchase the
company’s signature product, whose price fell and fell over the
years, from around $950 in 1909 to a low of $290 in 1926. 17
Were Ford’s the whole story of the automobile industry and, by
extension, American manufacturing in the 1920s, it would sound
something like this: higher wages, lower prices, and the mass
production of a standard item made what was once a luxury into a
commonly available commodity. But this is not the whole story.
Despite the Model T’s falling sticker price, major durable goods
generally cost more in relation to other products in the 1920s than
they had before the war. Americans did not buy these products in
such quantities because they were cheap: they bought despite the
expense. 18
Ford’s inexpensive, standard Model T made it possible for more,
different people to own cars. But at some point, everyone who
could afford a car would have one, and then who would buy?
General Motors (GM) decided to make sure that the same people
would keep buying different cars: it introduced planned
obsolescence by annually changing its models, and to allow for the
extravagance of regular new cars, GM began extending credit
through the General Motors Acceptance Corporation. 19
Often the ready credit of the 1920s came dear, at an annual interest
rate of around 30 percent on an installment plan for a new car. 20
Even though moralists—Henry Ford among them—fretted over
the ever-expanding definition of what Americans needed to buy,
14
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
consumers themselves hearkened to the doctrine Advertising and
Selling promulgated in 1926: ‘‘every free-born American has a
right to name his own necessities.’’ 21 Through the decade the list of
these new necessities grew.
Yet credit could not stretch cash infinitely. Installment plans sent
bills with clockwork regularity. Americans’ income did not arrive
with equal reliability: cyclical unemployment always loomed,
and social insurance against it scarcely existed. So buyers had to
take considerable care before they plunged into long-running
debt. Any added uncertainty in consumers’ outlook might make
them wait, just a while, to see what might happen to affect
their paychecks. In a time of economic crisis, even a short
pause in purchasing could slow or even stop the nation’s assembly
lines.
As Americans eagerly heeded the advertisers’ blandishments, they
ran closer to the limits on their good fortune. The countries
borrowing from the United States found out beginning in 1928
what happened when American credit dried up, and soon after
Americans found out what happened when their own credit-fueled
spending slowed. Both looked for the source of their problems and
for possible solutions at the headwaters of debt in Wall Street.
If the world economy of the 1920s consisted of concentric circles,
the outside ring held peoples remote from the industrial center and
little touched by its booms and busts. The next ring inward
included the industrial nations tied by debts to the United States.
Next from them dwelt most of the Americans themselves, divided
further into finer rings: those still struggling to get by, then those
better off if perhaps in hock to fund their routine purchases, and
then the minority—maybe under 10 percent—of Americans who
owned stocks. 22
And inward at last from them lived the near-
aristocracy, the moneymen who made decisions that determined
how easily everyone else could get their credit and who increasingly
fidgeted as they watched the stock-tickers.
15
T h e W
o rld
in D e b t
The best-connected and most diligent public servants of their day
worked on Wall Street and around it in lower Manhattan. In the
1920s they included the once and future Supreme Court Justice
Charles Evans Hughes; the once and future Secretary of War
Henry Stimson; the future New York governor Herbert Lehman;
and the future president and sometime foe of all that Wall Street
stood for, Franklin Roosevelt. 23
They handled mergers, stock
offerings, and all the great business of the nation’s businesses.
They also, along with their less reputable neighbors, handled other
transactions. For example, with a sufficient sum of capital a group
of investors could establish a ‘‘pool’’ specifically for the purpose of
manipulating a stock. Members of the pool would buy and sell to
one another at times and in increments calculated to tell a
particular story to an outsider watching the ticker tape. The
numbers on the tape showing the bare facts of trading did not lie,
but the pattern of numbers might deceive an imaginative observer
eager to know what the insiders knew. The ebb and flow of sales
conducted among the members of a pool would intimate to an
obsessed investor that someone, somewhere, had inside
information that a company’s stock should rise. Investors would
flock to the pool stock, driving its price up. Then, when it seemed
they had driven it as far as it would go, the original members of
the pool would cash in, sending the price back down to its
former level. It happened all the time and was not illegal.
Nor was it even secret: the Wall Street Journal reported on the
doings of pool stocks, published information about who led which
pools, and trafficked regularly in the opinions of analysts as to
which stocks best attracted uninformed enthusiasm (‘‘anything
which has electricity or light or power in its title,’’ one analyst
reported). 24
Americans sometimes distinguished between this sort of
activity, which they called ‘‘speculation,’’ and ordinary purchase
of stock, which they called ‘‘investing.’’ Investors bought stock
based on the soundness of the underlying enterprise over the long
16
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
term, choosing securities on the basis of whether they thought the
company would do its business competently in the months and
years to come. Speculators bought and sold stock based on their
intuitions as to everyone else’s impulses in the market that day.
And as speculative activity overshadowed investment, more
speculators came into the market, and more observers worried.
By 1928, Wall Street men knew, and the Wall Street Journal
affirmed, that they were working in ‘‘the kind of market that makes
for larger commissions than profits.’’ 25
Even so, increasing
numbers of Americans wanted to play this evidently rigged game.
People flocked to the big money, hoping to buy into the inner
circle. Even a loss could give them the thrill of having brushed up
against the big men.
Watching the increase in trading on the exchanges and in the
borrowing to trade on the exchanges, the Federal Reserve decided
to make it more expensive to borrow money. In June of 1928 the
Federal Reserve Bulletin noted ‘‘an unprecedented volume of
transactions on the exchange and a continued rise in security
prices’’ while ‘‘brokers’ loans reached a record figure . . . and
continued to increase.’’ So the Federal Reserve began ‘‘withdrawing
funds from the money market.’’ 26
Yet speculation flourished into the new year. Early in 1929, just
before Herbert Hoover’s inauguration as president, the Federal
Reserve warned publicly that it did not wish banks to use its credit
for ‘‘maintaining speculative security loans.’’ 27
Although
speculation continued at a high rate, U.S. overseas investment did
not: capital leaving America averaged around $800 million
annually from 1925 to 1928, rising to $1,250 million in 1928, but
fell to $628 million in 1929 and averaged about $360 million
annually from 1929 to 1932. 28
The Federal Reserve’s tighter
monetary policy helped slow American capital going to foreign
countries. Nations like Germany, which had depended on
American loans, began to struggle under this handicap.
17
T h e W
o rld
in D e b t
In later years, pronouncements reflecting incautious optimism, an
insistence that everyone should become rich, that everything was
for the best—comments so comforting to contemporaries and so
reckless in retrospect—became a staple of every story about the
Great Crash. And such remarks showed up all over in the weeks
before they altogether ceased. Newspapers regularly sought the
cheery views of professional soothers, who obligingly declared that
they saw smooth sailing ahead. But by the late 1920s, a growing
number of bankers and policymakers had the impression that the
world simply could not sustain the current state of its finances.
Both around the globe and within the United States too many
people had borrowed too much money for unproductive purposes.
The financier Bernard Baruch wrote, ‘‘Whereas it is wise to buy
things on the partial payment plan that will result in time in
increased economies and better living, at the same time it can be
overdone. I am afraid it has now been overdone.’’ 29
Too few reliable investments remained. And even though only a
few Americans actually bought and sold stocks, the market had
become a kind of entertainment, a set-piece of idle chat. In itself,
this prevalence of market talk warned those in the know that it was
time to get out before it was too late. The financier Joseph
P. Kennedy, who by summer of 1929 had sold out of his major
holdings and kept his money in cash, advised a friend that ‘‘Only a
fool holds out for the top dollar.’’ 30
Self-aware fools went into the
market assuming that still greater fools had yet to buy in. It took a
shrewd judge of national character to decide just when the United
States would run through its supply of fools.
Generally, those with means to leave Manhattan in summer
regarded as fools those who stayed. Yet in August of 1929,
traditionally a time to flee the city’s unreasonable heat, the
moneymen stayed in town to see if they could beat the big bull
market as it rose. Even through Labor Day, even through hot days
of high humidity, to the September 3 peak of market prices, they
stayed. Then a few days later the market dropped a bit. A couple of
18
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
weeks later it dropped a bit more. 31
The heat broke too. Rumors
spread that the pool operators had decided to see if they could
work their wiles in reverse and drive prices down. In the next
weeks the market slid, rallied, and slid again.
Through the morning of October 24, in the streets of New York,
crowds walked quietly downtown to Wall Street where they gathered
silently and stood looking at the New York Stock Exchange, as if
suddenly its abstract activities could become manifest, giving
evidence of the disaster now plainly happening to them all. 32
That
was Black Thursday. The market rallied afterward but then fell
again. The oil tycoon John D. Rockefeller announced that ‘‘there is
nothing in the business situation towarrant thedestruction of values
that has taken place’’ and that he was busy buying. 33
Neither this
gesture nor others like it shored up stock prices. By mid-November,
more than a third of the stock market’s value had vanished. 34
This fall in value immediately afflicted only a few Americans. But
so closely had the others watched the market and regarded it as an
index of their fates that they suddenly stopped much of their
economic activity. As the economist Joseph Schumpeter later
wrote, ‘‘people felt that the ground under their feet was giving
way.’’ 35
Facing a dubious future, Americans made important
decisions not to buy. Particularly, they stopped buying the
expensive durable goods like cars that they had learned to buy on
credit. Each signature on an installment-plan contract represented
a consumer’s prediction about his or her ability to pay in the future.
Suddenly Americans no longer felt able to see far enough ahead to
make sound forecasts. Within a few months of the crash new car
registrations had fallen by almost a quarter of their September
number. 36
In 1930 spending on consumer durables fell by 20
percent. 37
Factories closed and banks failed. Unemployment more
than doubled its 1929 level.
In 1931 John Maynard Keynes visited the United States and in
a lecture attributed the increasingly severe Depression to
19
T h e W
o rld
in D e b t
‘‘extraordinary imbecility.’’ 38
On this point observers generally do
agree: someone had blundered and, given the structure of global
finance after World War I, that someone must have had an address
ending in ‘‘United States of America.’’ The principal candidate,
then and later, was Herbert Hoover, who in his memoirs defended
himself by agreeing with the earlier Keynes: ‘‘the primary cause
of the Great Depression’’ Hoover wrote, ‘‘was the war of 1914–
1918.’’ 39
But Hoover stood little chance of escaping blame. By 1930
Joseph Kennedy was already calling one of Hoover’s backers to say,
‘‘jot down the name of the next president. . . . It’s Franklin
D. Roosevelt.’’ 40
Notes
1. John Maynard Keynes, The Economic Consequences of the Peace
(London: 1919), 213.
2. On Keynes’s critique of reparations, see Niall Ferguson, The Pity of
War: Explaining World War I (New York: Basic Books, 1999),
395–432.
3. Keynes, Economic Consequences, 8.
4. Christopher Blattman, Michael A. Clemens, and Jeffrey G.
Williamson, ‘‘Who Protected and Why? Tariffs the World Around,
1870–1938,’’ in Conference on the Political Economy of
Globalization (2002), 30.
5. Eric Rauchway, Blessed among Nations: How the World Made
America (New York: Hill and Wang, 2006), 156.
6. Keynes, Economic Consequences, 7.
7. Ibid., 211.
8. Edward Hallett Carr, The Twenty Years’ Crisis, 1919–1939, 2nd ed.
(London: Macmillan, 1962), 234.
9. Immigration Act, chap. 25 of 9–10 George V, p. 7, sec. 13, consulted
online 2/27/2007, www.canadiana.org/ECO/ItemRecord/
9_08048.
10. Rauchway, Blessed among Nations, 157.
11. Barry Eichengreen, ‘‘The Origins and Nature of the Great Slump
Revisited,’’ Economic History Review 45, no. 2 (1992): 223.
12. George Soule, Prosperity Decade: From War to Depression,
1917–1929 (New York: Rinehart, 1947), 220.
20
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
13. Martha L. Olney, Buy Now, Pay Later: Advertising, Credit, and
Consumer Durables in the 1920s (Chapel Hill: University of North
Carolina Press, 1991), 91.
14. Ibid., 40.
15. Peter Fearon, War, Prosperity, and Depression: The U.S. Economy,
1917–1945 (Oxford: Philip Allan, 1987), 55–56.
16. Soule, Prosperity Decade, 164.
17. John Bell Rae, American Automobile Manufacturers
(Philadelphia: Chilton Company, 1959), 107–9; John Bell Rae, The
American Automobile (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press,
1965), 61, 88.
18. Olney, Buy Now, 182.
19. Roland Marchand, Advertising the American Dream: Making Way
for Modernity, 1920–1940 (Berkeley: University of California
Press, 1985), 156; Olney, Buy Now, 127.
20. Olney, Buy Now, 115.
21. Marchand, Advertising the American Dream, 160.
22. Peter Fearon, Origins and Nature of the Great Slump, 1929–1932
(Atlantic Highlands, NJ: Humanities Press, 1979), 34.
23. John Brooks, Once in Golconda: A True Drama of Wall
Street, 1920–1938 (New York: Wiley Investment Classics, 1999),
58–59.
24. ‘‘Market Comment,’’ Wall Street Journal, 3/21/1928, 22.
25. ‘‘Broad Street Gossip,’’ Wall Street Journal, 1/13/1928, 2.
26. Federal Reserve Bulletin 14:6 (June 1928), 373.
27. John Kenneth Galbraith, The Great Crash, 1929 (Boston:
Houghton Mifflin, 1972), 38.
28. United Nations, International Capital Movements during the
Inter-War Period (New York: Arno, 1979), 10, table 1.
29. Bernard M. Baruch, Baruch, 2 vols. (New York: Holt, 1957–60),
2:218.
30. Richard J. Whalen, The Founding Father: The Story of Joseph
P. Kennedy (New York: New American Library, 1964), 104.
31. Brooks, Once in Golconda, 110.
32. Ibid., 117.
33. ‘‘Rockefeller Buys, Allaying Anxiety,’’ New York Times, 10/31/1929, 1.
34. Brooks, Once in Golconda, 119.
35. Joseph A. Schumpeter, Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical,
and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process (New York:
McGraw-Hill, 1939), 2:911.
21
T h e W
o rld
in D e b t
36. Christina D. Romer, ‘‘The Great Crash and the Onset of the Great
Depression,’’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 105, no. 3 (1990):
606.
37. Fearon, Origins and Nature, 34.
38. Robert Skidelsky, John Maynard Keynes: The Economist as
Saviour, 1920–1937, vol. 2, John Maynard Keynes (London:
1992), 391.
39. Herbert Hoover, Memoirs, 3 vols. (New York: Macmillan, 1951),
3:2.
40. Whalen, Founding Father, 113.
22
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Chapter 2
The Hoover Years
In the spring of 1931 Senator Robert Wagner (D-NY) claimed that
President Herbert Hoover had, in the face of crisis, ‘‘but clung to
the time-worn Republican policy: to do nothing and when the
pressure becomes irresistible to do as little as possible.’’ 1 Hoover
did not ‘‘do nothing,’’ but he did not do enough either. Instead he
followed a general policy for crisis management he had already
clearly established.
Indeed, when Hoover ran for president in 1928, Americans
associated him with competence in a crisis. Some Republican
leaders showed skepticism; Calvin Coolidge, whom Hoover served
as secretary of commerce, complained, ‘‘That man has offered me
unsolicited advice for six years, all of it bad.’’ 2 But a new emergency
had reminded Americans of Hoover’s virtues.
Rains swelled the Mississippi River early in 1927, and in the
middle of April the levees near Cairo, Illinois, collapsed. Hundreds
of thousands of acres disappeared beneath the water, and more
levees burst. Coolidge, who had to this point preferred hopeful
inaction, now appointed Hoover to head an emergency committee.
A successful mining engineer, Hoover had gone into public service
after making his fortune. During World War I, Woodrow Wilson
made Hoover head of the effort to provide food and other relief to
the war’s dispossessed, and Hoover earned a reputation as a
23
logistical genius. ‘‘He is certainly a wonder and I wish we could
make him President of the United States,’’ Assistant Secretary of
the Navy Franklin Roosevelt wrote in 1920. 3 Hoover owed his
reputation partly to his talent of organizing and using bureaucracy,
and partly to his talent at organizing and using the press. ‘‘[T]he
world lives by phrases,’’ he once said. 4
As head of the 1927 flood-relief effort, Hoover showed both the
extent and limits of these talents. He organized and managed
evacuations, saving lives; he oversaw the establishment of camps to
house refugees; he backed federal control of river management
to forestall future disasters. Hoover also turned a blind eye as
southern whites prevented black evacuees from leaving guarded
camps lest the South lose its labor supply. And he used whites’ fear
to his advantage, threatening local businessmen by saying, ‘‘I’ll
send your niggers north starting tonight,’’ if they did not contribute
money to a reconstruction fund. 5
Like the engineer he was, Hoover could build a machine to solve a
problem, but he expected someone else to operate it. He
accumulated $13 million in funds for reconstruction loans and
made sure everyone knew it, but he did not ensure that the money
would get lent to the stricken area, and the vast majority of it was
not. Further, although he favored massive federal spending on
engineering improvements in river management, he opposed
increasing the government’s humanitarian role, declaring, ‘‘No
relief to flood sufferers by Congress is desirable.’’ 6
As a prospective presidential nominee, Hoover knew he had to
promise loyalty and attention to the habitually Republican
black voters, without alienating potential white voters. He let
African American leaders know he favored a reconstruction plan
to subdivide the large farms in the flooded region into small
plots for black farmers. But he thereafter declined to support the
plan—or the black evacuees—in any substantial way. 7 The flood
gave Hoover the ability to claim that he could show grace
24
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
under pressure. Doubters were few, though sometimes
acute: the Baltimore journalist H. L. Mencken wrote that
Hoover’s ‘‘achievements all diminish rather than increase on
analysis.’’ 8
For the 1928 election Hoover’s record turned out not to matter
much. Hoover won not because of what he had done but because of
what his opponent, Al Smith, was: a Catholic. Smith was many
other things—most notably, governor of New York, in whose
assembly he had also served. New Yorkers knew him as a
progressive who had helped reform the state constitution and
investigate the infamous Triangle factory fire. Smith had backed
bills for workplace health and safety and against child labor. 9 But
his accomplishments and Hoover’s alike vanished amid a war of
symbols waged with Hoover’s preferred weapons: phrases. While
Hoover kept his distance from the worst slurs, his allies attacked
Smith for representing the ‘‘sneering, ridiculing . . . foreign-
populated city of New York,’’ for opening the way to ‘‘card playing,
cocktail drinking, poodle dogs, divorces, novels, stuffy rooms,
dancing, evolution, Clarence Darrow, overeating, nude art, prize
fighting, actors, greyhound racing, and modernism.’’ 10
What in hindsight looks like a critical election—the choice of a
leader for a period of profound crisis—turned on these
insubstantial issues of cultural conflict. The election mattered for
two major reasons: it left the Republicans in control of government
on the eve of the Depression, and it put Hoover, who opposed
public relief even in crisis and who believed in the power of phrases
to shape the world, in charge of the federal response to economic
calamity.
On October 25, 1929, the day after Black Thursday, Hoover told
reporters, ‘‘The fundamental business of the country, that is the
production and distribution of commodities, is on a sound and
prosperous basis.’’ 11 Hoover’s message was, in the Wall Street
Journal’s words, ‘‘in harmony’’ with the leading bankers and
25
T h e H o o v e r Y e a rs
leading industrialists, who emphasized that ‘‘the break . . . was a
technical one within the market and not based on fundamentals.’’ 12
A few weeks later, Hoover repeated his belief in the soundness of
American enterprise, saying, ‘‘Any lack of confidence in the
economic future or the basic strength of business in the United
States is foolish. Our national capacity for hard work and
intelligent cooperation is ample guaranty of the future.’’ 13
Hoover relied heavily on the idea of ‘‘intelligent cooperation.’’ He
saw himself as cheerleader to American enterprise, not as a referee,
coach, or player in the economy: he would call for teamwork and
hope to see it produced. He invited important figures in American
industry to meet, asking them to reason together, planning how
to keep the crash from turning into a depression. He urged
employers not to cut wage rates, and they agreed to cooperate. 14
Hoover went further still in his requests, asking state and local
politicians to hasten and augment their spending on roads and
other public works, believing that in various government treasuries
there lay ‘‘a substantial reserve for prompt expanded action.’’ 15
None of these strategies required much action from anyone in the
federal government, beyond uttering the occasional encouraging
phrase. None providedany immediate relief toAmericans. None cost
the federal government money. All depended on people outside
Washington, DC, to stop the disaster. None worked. The
businessmen’s pledge to uphold wage rates said nothing about
whether they would reduce hours or lay workers off, and they did
both. As early as January 1930, Business Week reported that ‘‘Some
automotive companies. . . discharged employees with what seemed
precipitous haste.’’ 16 Smaller employers, too numerous and minor to
get an invitation to Washington, did not feel bound by the wage
pledge.Accordingly,unemploymentroseand overallwagesdropped,
even in cases where the nominal rate of pay stayed the same.
Nor were local and state governments able to respond effectively to
Hoover’s plea. They spent some money on construction projects,
26
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
but as the crisis continued they had less to spend. Tax revenue
fell and the bill for local poor relief rose. These two draining effects
on local budgets forced local governments, by the hundreds, to
delay, if not repudiate, their debt payments. 17 These government
defaults put pressure on another weak pillar in the Hoover plan:
his dependence on what he called, in November of 1929, ‘‘[t]he
magnificent working of the Federal Reserve system and the
inherently sound condition of the banks.’’ 18
This assessment
proved faulty.
Since beginning operations in 1914, the Federal Reserve System
had functioned like a central bank for the United States, regulating
the supply of credit in response to economic production. Central
banks were supposed also, as the British journalist Walter Bagehot
wrote in 1873, to ‘‘lend freely’’ in times of economic crisis,
forestalling panic.
But the officers of the Federal Reserve System had not established
their own clear set of rules for intervening in crises. Some
believed the system must act swiftly to forestall disaster; others
thought that the system should keep its credit in reserve unless the
need grew truly dire. The balance of opinion within the Federal
Reserve rested with the anti-interventionists, as did the balance
of opinion within the economic profession during the 1920s.
Mostly, economists thought that an economy in crisis should be
left alone and that weaker banks and firms should go under.
They thought that during a boom period, some businessmen
made poor calculations under the influence of excess optimism:
they borrowed too much, produced, and stocked too much in
anticipation of demand that would never materialize. Economists
thought that these poor calculations helped bring on a crisis in the
first place, and that the proper role of a downturn was to correct
these errors of judgment. As the most popular basic economics
textbook of the era said, ‘‘The period of depression, then, is one
in which . . . production is kept at a low level until surplus stocks
are disposed of, and new commitments are not made until there is
27
T h e H o o v e r Y e a rs
a reasonable assurance of profits. In other words, the period of
depression, gloomy and unpleasing as it is, serves as a breathing
spell for business[.]’’ 19
Moreover, even had economists generally agreed on the need for
intervention in time of crisis, the Federal Reserve’s officers would
have had difficulty knowing just when that crisis had deepened to
a point requiring their action. The U.S. government kept no regular
statistics on unemployment or on total economic output, nor did it
have a system of accounting for national income. 20
Debate among
Federal Reserve bankers often rested on anecdotal evidence or
assumptions about what was happening in the economy.
In consequence, while in the immediate wake of the Crash the
Federal Reserve System took some steps to make it easier for banks
to lend and borrow money, after a few months it did little. Some of
its members fretted over the relative inaction, noting that the
depression seemed to be spreading around the world, particularly
afflicting America’s debtors. In the spring of 1930, George L.
Harrison, governor of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
visited Europe and observed ‘‘a shortage of working capital, and
thus a restriction of purchasing power, in a number of
countries . . . affected by the stringent credit conditions prevailing
last year.’’ 21
Harrison believed the Federal Reserve would need to
lessen restraints on credit, but a majority of the System’s governors
disagreed.
The Federal Reserve’s caution worked together with the Congress
and the president to bring the international economy to a near
halt. On June 17, 1930, Hoover signed the Smoot-Hawley Tariff
into law, raising taxes on imports to America. The idea for a new
tariff bill had arisen in 1928 as a method of protecting American
farmers, who were suffering a long bad patch, from foreign
competition. By the time it passed, many farmers opposed its
provisions, as did newspaper editors, some manufacturing
executives, and a number of foreign governments that believed it
28
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
would cut the American market off from the rest of the world, with
dire consequences. Members of the automobile industry, which
accounted for 10 percent of American exports, were especially
alarmed. 22
A GM executive warned that ‘‘a creditor nation . . . must,
if it hopes to preserve its prosperity . . . buy foreign goods of every
possible description.’’ 23
Thomas Lamont, a partner in the J. P.
Morgan and Company investment bank, claimed he ‘‘almost went
down on my knees to beg Herbert Hoover to veto the asinine
Hawley-Smoot tariff.’’ 24
But a higher tariff looked to other constituencies like a good idea.
Republicans favored tariffs in response to economic complaint.
They had used one in the postwar depression of 1921, and
it seemed to work then. So they did it again, by partisan
majorities—more than 90 percent of House Republicans voted
for the bill, more than 90 percent of House Democrats voted
against; in the Senate, 78 percent of Republicans were for, and
86 percent of Democrats were against. 25
The aftermath seemed to prove the critics correct. In the years that
followed, other countries retaliated by erecting their own tariff
barriers, and world trade fell by one quarter of its volume. Blocking
other countries from their American markets made it harder for
foreign powers to repay their debts outstanding from World War I.
As one writer explained in the New York Times, ‘‘there is not
enough gold in the world to pay America; therefore America must
be paid by loans from America and by goods sold in America.’’ 26
With the restriction of credit in 1928, loans from America had
begun to fall off, and with the restriction of trade in 1930, goods
sold in America began to fall off. Payments to America would have
also to fall off, as countries sought to protect their own citizens.
Cutting down trade meant cutting down the international flow of
borrowed money.
At the end of 1930, the difficulty of borrowing money finally took
its toll. In the last two months of the year, bank failures imperiled
29
T h e H o o v e r Y e a rs
enormous sums on deposit, more money than suspensions had put
at risk in the preceding year. 27
Nor did the panicking end even
then; the spasmodic collapse of the American banking system
continued. During Hoover’s presidency, more than 20 percent of
American banks went under. 28
The American banking system had, contrary to Hoover’s
assurances, some inherent weaknesses. The laws of many states
prevented banks from establishing branch offices. Banks with
many interconnected branches, lending money in different places
and to different kinds of borrowers, depended less on the fortunes
of any single locality and could weather a crisis more easily, while
unbranched American banks, or unit banks, failed relatively easily.
States that allowed branch banking had stronger, more
competitive banks that drove out or absorbed weaker banks. These
states entered the Depression with a stronger, more stable financial
system. Likewise, the Canadian banking system, with extensive
branch banking, survived the Depression largely intact. 29
The Crash hit American banks hard. Some had made loans to fund
speculation; others held foreign assets that went bust, as American
loans overseas halted and other countries could no longer meet
their obligations. But most important, banks suffered because their
clients suffered and could no longer pay off loans or make new
deposits in their savings accounts. Payment on loans and new
deposits provided banks with their major source of income. As
banks’ income dried up, they could not pay their own creditors.
Increasingly they had to close their doors. 30
The Federal Reserve System, in keeping with the opinion of a
majority of its members that the dying banks were a natural, if
painful, part of the circle of life in modern business, did not
prevent these failures or forestall further ones. Their inaction
accorded with the prevailing orthodoxy of their day. But the
prevailing orthodoxy of the 1920s defied the older, and tested,
belief set forth by Bagehot in 1873 as well as the evidence before
30
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
them. Banks continued to fail, in great sickening waves of
calamity, each closure sending new ripples of fear far and wide.
Americans began to mistrust their banks altogether, which in turn
made it still more difficult for banks to get credit.
Much the same could be said of Hoover: while he hewed to the
respectable opinion of his day, he defied both the evidence of his
senses and a longer-established tradition that cried out for action.
And in consequence he too found it harder and harder to get credit
as he might have in normal times. Early in October of 1930,
Hoover emphasized the psychological causes of Americans’
troubles: ‘‘The income of a large part of our people is not reduced
by the depression . . . but is affected by unnecessary fears and
pessimism.’’ As to whether the government should take any action,
he allowed it might cut the tax on capital gains, which would
permit investors to keep more of their profits from trading. 31 A few
weeks later, on the anniversary of Black Thursday, Hoover quashed
rumors that he would call Congress into special session to take
action against unemployment. ‘‘No special session is necessary to
deal with employment,’’ he declared. ‘‘The sense of voluntary
organization and community spirit in the American people have
not vanished.’’ 32
Hoover’s belief in the power of encouraging
phrases abided: Americans needed to believe, he thought, in the
adequacy of voluntary, civic, nongovernmental action.
A few weeks later, an elite class of Americans lost their jobs all at
once: congressional Republicans. In the House of Representatives,
the Republicans lost fifty-two seats and yielded control to the
Democrats. 33
In the Senate, the Republicans lost eight seats,
leaving neither party with a clear majority.
On February 3, 1931, Hoover reiterated his opposition to federal
unemployment relief, explaining that he would favor it only ‘‘if the
time should ever come that the voluntary agencies of the country,
together with the local and State Governments, are unable to find
resources with which to prevent hunger and suffering.’’ 34
Like the
31
T h e H o o v e r Y e a rs
Federal Reserve, which kept its gold in vaults while banks failed,
Hoover would not open the federal treasury for relief until after
private and local public institutions collapsed. He opposed federal
relief on principle, believing that Americans risked being ‘‘plunged
into socialism and collectivism’’ if the federal government provided
aid directly to its citizens. 35
He did not keep faith with cooperative and local efforts entirely in
vain. Some businesses tried hard to keep employment stable.
General Electric cut back on the number of styles in which it
produced lightbulbs, and also committed to fifty weeks of work in
1931 for employees who had been with the firm for two years or
more. Some unions worked with their industries to establish
unemployment insurance funds. Some companies retrained their
workers, in order to ease their movement within the firm. Still
others established loans for the unemployed. 36
States did what
they could. Governor Franklin D. Roosevelt of New York requested
an emergency relief program of the state assembly in the summer
of 1931, and Albany responded by devoting $20 million, which
went to the relief of more than 300,000 families. Other states
followed suit, spending tens of millions of dollars to aid their
citizens. 37
Yet these efforts did not suffice. Consumers spent cautiously when
they had no confidence, and hardly at all when they had no jobs.
Businesses that depended on consumers’ continued confident
borrowing suffered. As James Farrell, the president of United
States Steel Company, told a congressional hearing late in 1931, ‘‘it
is difficult to create business beyond the demands of buyers.’’ 38
And as businesses laid off their workers, fewer and fewer
consumers had money to spend.
Hoover did not refrain entirely from federal action. In February
1931, he signed legislation creating a Federal Employment
Stabilization Board, tasked with timing and scaling federal
spending on construction to respond to unemployment. 39
But he
32
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
supported such laws reluctantly, telling an ally that he preferred ‘‘to
cut expenses and to give to the country and the world an exhibit of
a balanced budget,’’ and he opposed other legislation to expand
federal public works. 40
Hoover also ordered stricter enforcement
of anti-immigration legislation, and in March of 1931, the New
York Times reported the White House’s claim that ‘‘President
Hoover, in his efforts to relieve the unemployment situation . . . has
kept out of the country nearly 100,000 aliens who would have ben
[sic] admissible under normal business conditions.’’ 41
In June 1931, Hoover moved to halt the international propagation
of credit collapses, declaring a one-year moratorium on
intergovernmental debts. He had his eye particularly on Germany,
whose fiscal affairs were sinking ominously. ‘‘It is not,’’ the Times
declared, ‘‘that war is threatened there,’’ but rather that ‘‘[i]t is today
as if there were but a single nervous system for the entire civilized
world,’’ and an injury to one extremity affected the whole body. 42
The moratorium might have delayed a further international
financial collapse, but it could provide no immediate relief for
Americans. The unemployment rate continued to soar.
Retrospective estimates suggest it rose from about 9 percent in
1930 to about 16 percent in 1931 and then to an appalling 23
percent in 1932. During the Depression, government statisticians
sensitive to the deepening crisis and wishing to measure its
proportions developed the concepts and methods of measuring
and defining unemployment that underlie these modern
calculations. But their early work produced gloomy numbers,
contrary to what the Hoover administration wished to hear and
say. The president subjected the chief of the Bureau of Labor
Statistics to forcible retirement, as the New York Times reported:
‘‘ ‘Retired!’ he shouted. ‘Please don’t put it that way. It is not a
proper word.’ ’’ 43
In desperation, and in the beginning of his campaign for
reelection, Hoover approved a last set of policies for lifting the
33
T h e H o o v e r Y e a rs
Depression. Alarmed by the impending collapse of the California-
based Bank of America, Hoover called for emergency legislation
to relieve the nation’s banks. 44
In January of 1932, he signed into
law the Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC), capitalized at
$500 million and permitted to issue notes of up to $1.5 billion so
it could lend money, principally to financial institutions, and
thus act (as the Federal Reserve was not) as an energetic lender
of last resort and rescue the nation’s credit-providing institutions.
RFC operated on the theory that if it could ease pressure on banks,
eventually they would confer a similar comfort on their borrowers.
Within two weeks of its creation, it was making a hundred
loans a day. 45
Hoover also signed a bill allocating $125 million to the Federal
Land Bank system, a network of banks established in 1916 to
provide farm mortgages. The extra money would prop up the
banks in the face of defaulting borrowers and savers who
demanded their deposits. Likewise, in the summer of 1932, Hoover
signed into law a system of Home Loan Banks to shore up banks
that had lent money for homeowners’ mortgages. He signed a
further bill easing the restrictions on banks within the Federal
Reserve System and allowing the Federal Reserve Board greater
latitude in manipulating interest rates. 46
All these measures probably helped loosen restrictions on
credit and got bankers and businessmen to lend and borrow
more freely again, which might eventually have led to the
substantial reemployment of the American people. But they did
nothing immediate for non-banker Americans. Hoover’s
supporters unintentionally damned their own efforts, explaining
correctly that they did nothing directly for ordinary citizens. As
Secretary of the Treasury Ogden Mills explained, the president’s
policies ‘‘set free the recuperative and constructive forces within
business itself . . . so that the nation’s business might have an
opportunity to do for itself what the Government cannot hope to
do for it.’’ 47
34
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Hoover stood by the principles of relief he had established in
1927—encouraging phrases, widely publicized, and aid to lenders,
but no direct assistance to American workers. He disavowed any
direct connection to citizens, explaining that he thought the
presidency conferred ‘‘a power for leadership bringing
coordination of the forces of business and cultural life.’’ 48
He left
himself entirely open to criticism from Governor Roosevelt,
who declared in April of 1932 that ‘‘The present
administration . . . has either forgotten or it does not want to
remember the infantry of our economic army. These unhappy
times call for . . . plans . . . that build from the bottom up and not
from the top down, that put their faith once more in the forgotten
man at the bottom of the pyramid.’’ 49
Roosevelt’s speech brought
disapproval even from members of his own party, for stirring up
the masses against the rich. But by summer he would be the
Democratic nominee for president, and in November he would put
Herbert Hoover out of work, winning the presidency by a
landslide, on the hope that he, as Hoover on principle would not,
might bring relief to ordinary Americans.
Notes
1. ‘‘Wagner Puts Party in Progressive Role,’’ New York Times, 5/15/31, 2.
2. John M. Barry, Rising Tide: The Great Mississippi Flood of 1927
and How It Changed America (New York: Simon and Schuster,
1997), 270.
3. Timothy Walch and Dwight M. Miller, eds., Herbert Hoover and
Franklin D. Roosevelt: A Documentary History (Westport, CT:
Greenwood, 1998), 6.
4. Barry, Rising Tide, 266.
5. Ibid., 368.
6. Ibid., 401.
7. Ibid., 384–93.
8. H. L. Mencken, On Politics: A Carnival of Buncombe, ed. Malcolm
Moos (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1956), 148.
9. Robert A. Slayton, Empire Statesman: The Rise and Redemption of
Al Smith (New York: Free Press, 2001), 98.
10. Ibid., 314, 316.
35
T h e H o o v e r Y e a rs
11. ‘‘Hoover Asserts Business Sound,’’ Wall Street Journal,
10/26/1929, 1.
12. ‘‘Leaders Call Break Technical,’’ Wall Street Journal,
10/26/1929, 13.
13. ‘‘Text of Hoover’s Announcement of Plan for National Conference
on Business Aid,’’ New York Times, 11/16/1929, 1.
14. Albert U. Romasco, The Poverty of Abundance (New York: Oxford
University Press, 1965), 29.
15. ‘‘Text of Hoover’s Announcement,’’ New York Times, 11/16/1929, 1.
16. Romasco, Poverty of Abundance, 59.
17. Lester V. Chandler, American Monetary Policy, 1928–41 (New
York: Harper and Row, 1971).
18. ‘‘Text of Hoover’s Announcement,’’ New York Times, 11/16/1929, 1.
(Capitalization of ‘‘system’’ as in original.)
19. Chandler, American Monetary Policy, 119.
20. Ibid., 116.
21. Ibid., 151.
22. Barry Eichengreen, ‘‘The Political Economy of the Smoot-Hawley
Tariff,’’ NBER Working Paper no. 2001 (1986), 17.
23. ‘‘Urge Tariff Cuts to Aid World Amity,’’ New York Times,
6/10/1930, 2.
24. David M. Kennedy, Freedom from Fear: The American People in
Depression and War, 1929–1945 (New York: Oxford University
Press, 1999), 50.
25. Douglas Irwin, ‘‘From Smoot-Hawley to Reciprocal Trade
Agreements: Changing the Course of U.S. Trade Policy in the
1930s,’’ in The Defining Moment: The Great Depression and the
American Economy in the Twentieth Century, ed. Claudia Goldin,
Eugene N. White, and Michael D. Bordo (Chicago: The University
of Chicago Press, 1998), 334.
26. Edwin L. James, ‘‘Peril to War Debts Seen in our Tariff,’’ New York
Times, 6/18/1930, 1.
27. Ben S. Bernanke, ‘‘Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in
the Propagation of the Great Depression,’’ American Economic
Review 73, no. 3 (1983): 262.
28. Chandler, American Monetary Policy, 105.
29. Mark Carlson and Kris James Mitchener, ‘‘Branch Banking, Bank
Competition, and Financial Stability,’’ NBER Working Paper
no. 11291 (2005); Richard S. Grossman, ‘‘The Shoe That Didn’t
Drop: Explaining Banking Stability During the Great Depression,’’
Journal of Economic History 54, no. 3 (1994).
36
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
30. Chandler, American Monetary Policy, 105–6.
31. ‘‘HooverAsks Bankersto Take Lead,’’NewYork Times,10/3/1930, 1.
32. ‘‘Work for Jobless Put at $450,000,000,’’ New York Times,
10/25/1930, p. 4.
33. Clerk of the House website, www.house.gov, consulted 2/27/2007.
The Seventy-first Congress had 270 Republicans and the Seventy-
second had 218.
34. ‘‘Text of President Hoover’s Statement,’’ New York Times,
2/4/1931, 2.
35. Joan Hoff Wilson, Herbert Hoover, Forgotten Progressive (Prospect
Heights, IL: Waveland, 1992), 151.
36. Romasco, Poverty of Abundance, 135–38.
37. Ibid., 169–70.
38. Ibid., 139.
39. ‘‘Wagner Act Signed bythe President,’’ New York Times, 2/11/1931, 2.
40. Wilson, Herbert Hoover, Forgotten Progressive, 150.
41. ‘‘Alien Order Bars 96, 885 in 5 Months,’’ New York Times,
3/27/1931, 22.
42. ‘‘No Splendid Isolation,’’ New York Times, 6/20/1931, 11.
43. ‘‘Labor Commissioner Stewart Quits Post,’’ New York Times,
7/3/1932, 3.
44. James S. Olson, Herbert Hoover and the Reconstruction Finance
Corporation, 1931–1933 (Ames: Iowa State University Press,
1977), 33–35.
45. Ibid., 42.
46. Romasco, Poverty of Abundance, 190–93.
47. Ibid., 197.
48. Ibid., 200.
49. James S. Olson, Saving Capitalism: The Reconstruction Finance
Corporation and the New Deal, 1933–1940 (Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1988), 55.
37
T h e H o o v e r Y e a rs
Chapter 3
Americans in the Depression
The United States endured depressions before the 1930s, but the
Great Depression, in its breadth and duration, and in the
immediacy of its chronicling, produced also a great compression.
The newly interconnected country (Americans in their twenties
could remember when there were still western territories, rather
than fully fledged states) now had radio and newsreels throughout
its towns to show itself how its people suffered. As the Depression
lasted, it put the middle class more and more into the
circumstances of the poor and encouraged empathy across class
lines.
Americans in their forties could remember the last great
depression, when the global upheaval of the middle 1890s led to
frightening strikes and sent armies of the unemployed tramping
the countryside, seeking work they could not find. In the midst of
that depression, most voters cast their ballots against William
Jennings Bryan, the Democrat who claimed to speak for the
downtrodden. But Americans of this generation could remember
also how the 1890s fell during an age of globalization, and
remembered how so many of the country’s workers then had been
immigrants, literally of another people. By the Great Depression,
this was no longer so true. World War I slowed immigration almost
to a halt, and restrictionist legislation of the 1920s pulled America’s
golden door nearly shut. No longer did the factories seem to teem
38
with newly arrived foreign workers. And so closed one of the gaps
that had, a generation before, separated the middling sort from the
working class.
The severity of the Depression’s misfortune also diminished the
distance between the comfortable and the hard-up. So many
moved so quickly from one category to another that the employed
increasingly identified with their fellow countrymen who were out
of work. The gap between income brackets shrank. And where
once, not long before, middle-class Americans might reflexively
have considered lazy anyone who was unemployed, where once
they might have considered radical anyone who claimed the
government owed them some assistance, in the 1930s they
increasingly saw the suffering millions among them as people
much like themselves, who had worked to build the country that
seemed now to be falling apart. This diminishing distance between
classes helps to explain why Americans embraced E. Y. Harburg’s
song ‘‘Brother, Can You Spare a Dime?’’, repeatedly played
throughout the Depression.
They used to tell me I was building a dream
And so I followed the mob.
When there was earth to plow or guns to bear
I was always there right on the job . . .
Once I built a railroad, I made it run,
Made it race against time.
Once I built a railroad, now it’s done
Brother, can you spare a dime?
As Harburg explained, ‘‘This is the man who says: I built the
railroads. I built that tower. I fought your wars. . . . I made an
investment in this country. Where the hell are my dividends?’’ 1
Americans who were not themselves out of work—and they were
the majority of the workforce—could have ignored this angry and
anguished question, as they had at other times in the country’s
history. But as times got harder, Americans who had something,
39
A m e ric
a n s in
th e D e p re ssio
n
however little, to spare accepted the justice of the claim,
‘‘showering dimes and quarters upon outstretched hands,’’ as the
New York Times wrote early in 1933. 2 The country that so easily
and so recently divided along racial and ethnic lines now drew,
even if slightly, closer together.
So quickly after the crash did the crisis grow to such an appalling
extent that its full dimensions resisted comprehension. When the
unemployment rate ran to around a quarter of the workforce in
1932, about 11.5 million Americans had no work. To put this
in some perspective, we might imagine that nearly the entire
population of New York, then the most populous state, had no
jobs: that from the easternmost tip of Long Island to the shores
of Lake Erie, from the Canadian border to Pennsylvania,
nobody had work.
But this perspective does not give quite the right picture. Some of
the people of New York—children, dependent wives—would
ordinarily have held no formal jobs. And the 11.5 million out of
work represented only the workers who had no paycheck. Many
of them had families who depended on them for a living. So the
11.5 million who had no jobs represented something like thirty
million Americans who had lost their source of income. 3 Perhaps
a quarter of the entire population, therefore, found itself without
adequate means to buy shelter or food. 4
Nor indeed do these numbers, as awful an impact as they make, tell
us quite all we should know about the Depression’s scope. In
unemployment’s shadow ran underemployment: those Americans
lucky enough to keep their jobs often saw their hours and pay
reduced. Employers wanted to keep their skilled workers if they
could, so rather than lay people off, they urged their staff to share
the burden. To many employees it seemed only fair. And so by the
summer of 1932, more than half of American workers did their
jobs part-time, keeping on average 59 percent of a full-time job and
of full-time pay. 5
40
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Americans in need asked for help reluctantly, and when
circumstances forced them to seek help, they went to those closest
to them. But in the Depression, each of their customary sources of
support failed them, one by one. As a New York City official
explained in 1932, ‘‘when the breadwinner is out of a job he usually
exhausts his savings if he has any. . . . He borrows from his friends
and from relatives until they can stand the burden no longer. He
gets credit from the corner grocery store and the butcher shop, and
the landlord foregoes collecting the rent until interest and taxes
have to be paid and something has to be done. All of these
resources are finally exhausted over a period of time, and it
becomes necessary for these people, who have never before been in
want, to ask for assistance.’’ 6
When family and neighbors failed, workers could sometimes get
help from locally organized mutual assistance funds such as rainy-
day plans, or widows-and-orphans money set aside by a union or
1. These men stand in a New York City breadline in 1932.
41
A m e ric
a n s in
th e D e p re ssio
n
civic group. Often, Americans set up such plans within their
religious or ethnic communities, on the principle of pride, to
guard against one of their own having to go to charities or, what
felt even more degrading, public relief. So Polish Americans,
German Americans, church parishes and congregations, and
various other communities kept up aid agencies that tried to
provide for the unlucky among them and tide them over until work
came. ‘‘Let’s have pride enough not to sponge upon public support
when Catholic charity is still able to care for its own interest,’’ one
priest declared. 7
But these networks of support, sufficient to the occasional idle day
in a single industry, collapsed under the weight of need that now
pressed down on them. So increasingly people turned in shame to
public sources of relief, even though it cost them dearly, and
sometimes they clung to their self-respect long after they should
have, to save their lives, sought help. A doctor working in a free
clinic remembered, ‘‘The poor got some care, could go to free
dispensaries. The rich got good care because they could afford it.
There was this big middle class that was not getting any care. The
middle class got very much in the position of the poor
people. . . . People of that status would find it very difficult to accept
charity. . . . Every day . . . someone would faint on a streetcar. They’d
bring him in, and they wouldn’t ask any questions . . . they knew
what it was. Hunger. When he regained consciousness, they’d give
him something to eat.’’ 8
Historically, American cities had through their own treasuries
provided relief to their poor, but soon even cities could not help
their citizens. In 1932, a Detroit official put it this way:
Many essential public services have been reduced beyond the
minimum point absolutely essential to the health and safety of the
city. . . . The salaries of city employees have been twice
reduced . . . and hundreds of faithful employees . . . have been
furloughed. Thus has the city borrowed from its own future welfare
42
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
to keep its unemployed on the barest subsistence levels. . . . A wage
work plan which had supported 11,000 families collapsed last
month because the city was unable to find funds to pay these
unemployed—men who wished to earn their own support. For
the coming year, Detroit can see no possibility of preventing
wide-spread hunger and slow starvation through its own
unaided resources.9
Sometimes municipal funds might find their way to the needy
through nontraditional routes: in New York, where the Health
Department found that one in five of the city’s schoolchildren
suffered from malnutrition, public school teachers, threatened
with pay cuts, paid into a fund from their own pockets for the relief
of their pupils. 10
As civic organizations and governments crumbled
under the weight, often so did families. ‘‘A man is not a man
without work,’’ one of the unemployed told an interviewer. 11 Those
men who felt differently—who made for themselves a place in the
world outside the workplace, who as husbands and fathers and
friends and hobbyists knew what was worthwhile to strive for—
shouldered the burden of crisis more easily. But they were in the
minority. As one sociologist wrote, ‘‘The average American has the
feeling that work . . . is the only dignified way of life. . . . While
theoretically, economic activities are supposed to be the means to
the good life, as a matter of fact it is not the end, but the means
themselves, that have the greater prestige.’’ 12
More often than not, men took this sense of duty to heart. They
knew how closely their children watched them, how much hung on
their ability to get even a little work, how much joy it could bring to
a house, or at least how much sorrow it could hold off. As one man
who had been a boy during the Depression remembered,
A lot of fathers—mine, among them—had a habit of taking off.
They’d go to . . . look for work. . . . This left the family at home,
waiting and hoping that the old man would find something. And
there was always the Saturday night ordeal as to whether or not the
43
A m e ric
a n s in
th e D e p re ssio
n
old man would get home with his paycheck. . . . Heaven would break
out once in a while, and the old man would get a week’s work . . . that
smell of fresh sawdust on the carpenter’s overalls, and the fact
that Dad was home, and there was a week’s wages. . . . That’s the
good you remember. And then there was always the bad part.
That’s when you’d see your father coming home with the toolbox
on his shoulder. Or carrying it. That meant the job was over.13
Sometimes men who left to look for work never came back, finding
homes in doorways or subways or the communities of shacks on
the edges of cities or landfills that, soon enough, Americans
learned to call ‘‘Hoovervilles.’’ Children who were old enough and
independent might themselves leave, foraging on the road instead
of relying on overburdened parents. Usually such tramps were
young men prepared to fend for themselves, racing to catch
boxcars and steal rides. Sometimes the railroad detectives turned a
blind eye to their unscheduled human cargo, sometimes not.
Sometimes other travelers helped, sometimes they did not. In all,
maybe two million Americans made their homes on the road in the
years after the Crash. 14
When employers advertised jobs, they had their pick of workers
and could indulge their preferences, or prejudices. Increasingly,
they hired or kept on white men with work experience, leaving the
young and old, the women, and the African Americans
disproportionately represented among the unemployed. Before the
Crash, as women first entered the workforce in significant
numbers, Americans already found it easy to believe that if a
woman worked, she was doing it for frivolous spending money—
that properly, women would rely on men who, as heads of
households, would supply their wives and children with a living. In
the labor glut of the Depression, employers—sometimes by policy,
sometimes simply by habit—hired fewer married women and more
readily dismissed those they already had on the rolls. 15 Yet women
increasingly sought work, mainly to keep families afloat, though
sometimes to maintain a middle-class life in the face of the
44
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Depression. 16
Women faced a harder market than their fathers,
husbands, brothers, or sons. And if they had to leave their families,
life on the road presented an even greater threat of physical
exploitation than it posed to their male relations. Accounts of
women out of work and without family tell of them establishing
communities to protect themselves, sharing meager resources and
small rooms, scheduling shifts for the use of beds and clothes. One
politician remarked that the woman worker in America was ‘‘the
first orphan in the storm.’’ 17
If so, the black worker followed close behind her into the rough
weather. In the cities of the United States, African Americans lost
2. Squatters’ shacks populate the banks of the Willamette River in this
‘‘Hooverville’’ settlement near Portland, Oregon.
45
A m e ric
a n s in
th e D e p re ssio
n
their jobs much more quickly than their white counterparts. In
part they suffered a misfortune of historical timing: black
Americans, long a rural population, had on average moved to cities
less recently and had less opportunity to develop careers as skilled
laborers than white Americans. But a comparative lack of skills
accounted only partially for the high levels of African American
unemployment. Black workers noticed that they were ‘‘last hired,
first fired,’’ and that employers deliberately laid off black workers
to replace them with white ones. ‘‘So general is this practice that
one is warranted in suspecting that it has been adopted as a
method of relieving unemployment of whites without regard to the
consequences upon Negroes,’’ a National Urban League study
concluded in 1931. 18
These inequities in the job market ensured the Depression-era
working class actually in work, or nearest to it, looked much more
white, much more male, and overall much more uniform than the
working classes of earlier eras. The laborers who held jobs had
much visibly in common with one another, and the issues of
cultural conflict that so consumed Americans of earlier eras
diminished. The object of Americans’ solicitude became the
imperiled white, male head-of-household, whose hardship they
could understand as the nation’s concern. 19
These nationwide hardships crossed the lines between urban
and rural populations to an unprecedented degree.
Unemployment, as a cyclical problem, had plagued cities as long
as there had been cities, and Americans had a folk tradition of
returning to the countryside when the cities went into a slump.
Farm jobs traditionally enjoyed a resistance to the problems
that plagued cities, and in the Depression many Americans did
seek out the security of a subsistence farm—in 1932 the farm
population rose to the highest point it would reach between
the two world wars. 20
But a series of unfortunate events made
sure that the countryside suffered the Great Depression as the
cities did.
46
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Farm incomes reached their peak around World War I, when the
dangers of shipping and general scarcity drove up the price of
agricultural produce. High prices inspired farmers to put more
land under the plow. Newly available tractors let them do it
quickly. Then in the postwar depression, farm prices fell sharply;
even after they rose again in the middle 1920s, the prices of the
goods farmers had to buy rose higher still. The fresh prevalence of
farm machines made it cheaper to produce more agricultural
goods on a large scale, and as tractors appeared, mules and men
went away. ‘‘Tractored out’’ hands left the countryside to seek
opportunity elsewhere. 21
Even the new city prosperity hurt
farmers: as urban Americans improved their circumstances, they
chose their diets based on taste, rather than need. Once, a wider
waistband had signaled health and success, but now thin was
fashionable, and food producers’ income declined. Further,
farmers, like other Americans, took on considerable debt in their
expansion and mechanization, rendering them vulnerable to
shock. 22
When the Crash shook this system, the fragile supports for farmers
collapsed. Farm income tumbled downward. Creditors forced
farmers to sell their property to cover delinquent debt payments. 23
Often, and increasingly, farmers and their neighbors tried to
thwart attempts to dispossess them. They might band together and
buy property at a delinquency auction, then return it for free to the
owner, or they might threaten lawmen who sought forcibly to sell
property.
The weather conspired with the man-made calamity. Beginning in
1931, rainfall on the Great Plains lessened until it dropped below
the level necessary to sustain crops. Soon the earth would dry and
crack so that it could no longer hold itself together, and great winds
would simply blow it away. 24
The South suffered from its continuing peculiarity. Since slavery,
its people depended on poorly paid farm jobs to get by. Containing
47
A m e ric
a n s in
th e D e p re ssio
n
only about a quarter of the nation’s population, the South
accounted for more than 40 percent of America’s farmworkers,
and they were the worst-paid hands in the country. 25
Often they
were tenant farmers who owed their landlords a share of the crop
they produced and had little control over their livelihoods. ‘‘In
1929, me and my husband were sharecroppers,’’ one woman
recalled. ‘‘We made a crop that year, the owner takin’ all the crop.
This horrible way of livin’ with almost nothin’.’’ 26
As both progress and disaster pushed people off the farms, they
left, as able people throughout history have done, seeking better
chances. As they did before the Depression, many migrants went
West, to California, where the job market might be, and the
weather generally was, better. Luckier ones came by car: in 1931,
more than 800,000 automobiles entered the Golden State. 27
Less
fortunate travelers came by train: in a single month of 1932, the
Southern Pacific Railroad company, whose lines ran into and along
the length of California, figured it had evicted 80,000 freight-
hoppers from the cars it carried. 28
Many of both kinds of migrants
wound up encamped throughout California’s long valleys, living in
tents or small cabins, picking crops for what passed for a
living, surviving—or failing to—on beans and rice. Observers
figured more than a quarter of the children in such camps
suffered from malnutrition, and some of them died of it. 29
The image of Americans living with almost nothing, driven by
drought and storm from their homes, bent under hardship and
persevering by will, soon seared itself into the minds of people all
over the country. In later years, in reporters’ stories and in tales
survivors told, in enduring photographs by Walker Evans and
Dorothea Lange, and accounts by James Agee and Lorena Hickok,
these pictures of poverty in the land of dreamed plenty came to
represent the Depression.
But it is worth remembering too that they did not alone represent
the Depression, and in the dispassionate view of history, the
48
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
sudden affliction of the ordinarily affluent may have mattered
more. For example, not all the luckless migrants belonged to the
chronically poor or even the working class. Many simply found
themselves dispossessed as a region’s economy succumbed, entire,
to the collapse. ‘‘We were living in a very large house and making
good money,’’ the son of a successful tractor salesman recalled,
until ‘‘POW—Dad didn’t have a job anymore.’’ 30
As the whole country trembled, if it did not quite crumble, even
generally well-off Americans who rarely thought much or
concretely about the lot of the poor had suddenly an occasion to
think hard on the matter, even though they might not themselves
lack work, even though, perversely, the Depression allowed such
Americans to live better at lower cost, because sellers in
desperation had so lowered their prices. Yet nobody could live
quite without worry. They mended their shoe leather with
cardboard and stitched pieces of bedsheets together. 31 The recently
introduced brand of adhesive cellophane, Scotch Tape, sold well to
people trying to fix what they had, instead of buying new. 32
The crisis developed further, seeming ever more systemic, ever
more permanent, and Americans came increasingly to believe that
the unfortunate could not, by themselves, bear responsibility for
their plight, and that but for the grace of God almost any of the
nation’s citizens, however prudent and hard-working, might find
themselves out of luck one day. And as their own local
communities proved inadequate to the catastrophe, they listened
increasingly for national voices, which came to them over the
radio.
One such voice belonged to Father Charles Coughlin, whose weekly
radio broadcasts reached Americans nationwide. 33
Coughlin
began his radio career in a parish outside Detroit, taking to the
airwaves in the middle 1920s to defy the local Ku Klux Klan. His
talents and opinions on a widening variety of subjects won him an
ever larger audience. People said you could walk for blocks in
49
A m e ric
a n s in
th e D e p re ssio
n
America’s cities when Coughlin was on the radio and never miss a
word, as the priest’s message drifted out his loyal listeners’
windows into the street. Speaking over a nationwide network in
the Depression, he spoke increasingly about political matters. 34
Coughlin spoke to a mainly middle-class audience, to people who
liked things as they were before the Crash yet who did not own so
much that they could insulate themselves from the material or
psychological effects of the Depression. 35
Coughlin attacked
Communism but, as he told a congressional hearing, he thought
the greatest force for Communism in the world was an intransigent
capitalist like Henry Ford, who by denying his workers’ lesser,
reasonable claim for relief risked a revolutionary claim to
everything. 36
By 1932, Coughlin and his listeners had reason firmly
to put Herbert Hoover in the same intransigent category as Ford.
In his last summer as president, Hoover set himself against a new
claim for relief from a special category of Americans: war veterans.
In 1924 Congress had voted a special supplementary payment, or
bonus, to veterans of World War I based on the length and location
of service. The government issued certificates showing the amount
owing to each veteran, who could collect either in 1945 or upon his
death. As times grew leaner and veterans looked longingly at those
sums due in the distant future, they thought perhaps the
government might relent and pay them a little early. A bonus due
them on their deaths would not do much good, so perhaps they
could have it now. After all, Congress had just, at the president’s
urging, created the Reconstruction Finance Corporation, which
would channel as much as $2 billion to banks and railroads to keep
them afloat. ‘‘If the government can pay $2 billion to the bankers
and the railroads,’’ Coughlin wondered, ‘‘why cannot it pay the $2
billion to the soldiers?’’ 37
Some former soldiers who thought likewise decided to go to
Washington, DC, to stake their claim in person. The major, early
organization came from Portland, Oregon, but before long news of
50
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
the movement inspired other marchers, both singly and in groups.
Washington police began to prepare for the arrival of twenty
thousand men, who became known as the Bonus Army. The Secret
Service infiltrated the march to look for threats and found
‘‘Generally speaking there were few Communists . . . and they
had little effect on the men’s thinking. The veterans were
Americans, down on their luck, but by no means ready to
overthrow their government.’’ 38
On June 7, thousands of soldiers
paraded through the city in front of a hundred thousand
cheering onlookers. 39
Others among the capital’s defenders assessed the marchers
differently. General Douglas MacArthur, then U.S. Army chief of
staff, began gathering forces, including tanks, to defend the city
against the vagabond threat that began to camp, with the help of
city police, across the Anacostia River from the Capitol. Warned
repeatedly that they might look like subversives, the marchers
policed themselves vigorously, organizing courts and less formal
groups to throw out Communists. But it did them no good.
Congress adjourned without voting them relief, and the White
House and the army grew increasingly concerned the longer they
stayed. At the end of July, MacArthur resolved to, in his words,
‘‘break the back’’ of the bonus march with full military force.
Soldiers marched out, fixed bayonets, and fired tear gas on the
marchers and bystanders alike. Cavalry rode into the crowd; as
Major George S. Patton recalled, ‘‘Bricks flew, sabers rose and fell
with a comforting smack, and the mob ran.’’ 40
Afterward
MacArthur claimed he heard, as he generally did, cries of gratitude
from the bystanders. 41
MacArthur’s fans, if extant, were surely a minority. Newsreel
footage of the clash between the armed and unarmed armies
showed tanks rolling through Washington’s streets, the veterans’
camp burning, and smoke drifting past the Capitol dome.
MacArthur and Hoover said they did not believe the men were, in
the main, really veterans at all. But the images of American soldiers
51
A m e ric
a n s in
th e D e p re ssio
n
chasing poverty-stricken Americans petitioning their congressmen
elicited the sympathy of viewers. ‘‘I felt myself one of them,’’ one
woman said. 42
In Albany, the governor of New York state and Democratic
presidential nominee Franklin D. Roosevelt read about the Bonus
March in the New York Times. Looking at the coverage, he told an
aide that they scarcely needed to take Hoover seriously as an
opponent after this disaster. Roosevelt said he might feel sorry for
Hoover if he did not already feel sorry for the marchers. Indeed,
Roosevelt himself did not think the government could afford to pay
the men a bonus—indeed, he would veto a bonus bill as president—
but, he thought, the men still deserved some sympathetic attention.
He thought for a while, smoking. Still, he said, the men making
their claim on the government, abused by the administration,
‘‘made a theme for the campaign.’’ 43
Notes
1. William L. Manchester, The Glory and the Dream: A Narrative
History of America, 1932–1972 (Boston: Little, Brown, 1974), 27;
Studs Terkel, Hard Times: An Oral History of the Great Depression
(New York: New Press, 2000), 20–21.
2. ‘‘The Lyrical Mr. Harburg,’’ New York Times, 1/8/1933, X2.
3. Lester V. Chandler, America’s Greatest Depression, 1929–1941
(New York: Harper and Row, 1970), 34.
4. David E. Kyvig, Daily Life in the United States, 1920–1940: How
Americans Lived through the ‘‘Roaring Twenties’’ and the Great
Depression (Chicago: Ivan R. Dee, 2002), 208.
5. Chandler, America’s Greatest Depression, 35.
6. Ibid., 41.
7. Lizabeth Cohen, Making a New Deal: Industrial Workers in
Chicago, 1919–1939 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1990), 218–21.
8. Terkel, Hard Times, 145.
9. Chandler, America’s Greatest Depression, 44.
10. ‘‘20.5% of City Pupils Are Found Underfed,’’ New York Times,
10/29/1932, 17.
52
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
11. Mirra Komarovsky, The Unemployed Man and His Family (New
York: Arno Press, 1971), 133.
12. Ibid., 82.
13. Terkel, Hard Times, 107–8.
14. James R. McGovern, And a Time for Hope: Americans in the Great
Depression (Westport, CT: Praeger, 2000), 10.
15. Claudia Dale Goldin, Understanding the Gender Gap: An Economic
History of American Women (New York: Oxford University Press,
1990).
16. Winifred D. Wandersee Bolin, ‘‘The Economics of Middle-Income
Family Life: Working Women During the Great Depression,’’
Journal of American History 65, no. 1 (1978): 70–71.
17. William H. Chafe, The Paradox of Change: American Women in the
20th Century (New York: Oxford University Press, 1991), 71.
18. William A. Sundstrom, ‘‘Last Hired, First Fired? Unemployment
and Urban Black Workers During the Great Depression,’’ Journal
of Economic History 52, no. 2 (1992): 421.
19. See also Gary Gerstle, American Crucible: Race and Nation in the
TwentiethCentury (Princeton:PrincetonUniversity Press,2001),177.
20. Susan B. Carter et al., eds., Historical Statistics of the United
States, Earliest Times to the Present, Millennial Edition (New
York: Cambridge University Press, 2006), series Da2; Peter
Fearon, War, Prosperity, and Depression: The U.S. Economy,
1917–1945 (Oxford: Philip Allan, 1987), 176.
21. Kevin Starr, Endangered Dreams: The Great Depression in
California (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996), 224.
22. Chandler, America’s Greatest Depression, 56.
23. Ibid., 63.
24. Donald Worster, Dust Bowl: The Southern Plains in the 1930s
(New York: Oxford University Press, 1979), 11.
25. Kyvig, Daily Life, 211; Bruce J. Schulman, From Cotton Belt to
Sunbelt: Federal Policy, Economic Development, and the
Transformation of the South, 1938–1980 (Durham, NC: Duke
University Press, 1994), 3.
26. Terkel, Hard Times, 232.
27. Starr, Endangered Dreams, 23.
28. Ibid., 226.
29. Ibid., 229.
30. James N. Gregory, American Exodus: The Dust Bowl Migration
and Okie Culture in California (New York: Oxford University
Press, 1989), 16.
53
A m e ric
a n s in
th e D e p re ssio
n
31. Manchester, Glory and the Dream, 35.
32. Kyvig, Daily Life, 227.
33. Alan Brinkley, Voices of Protest: Huey Long, Father Coughlin, and
the Great Depression (New York: Vintage, 1983), 92.
34. Ibid., 94.
35. Ibid., 197–98.
36. Ibid., 102.
37. Paul Dickson and Thomas B. Allen, The Bonus Army: An American
Epic (New York: Walker and Company, 2004), 51.
38. Ibid., 82.
39. ‘‘7,000 in Bonus Army Parade in Capital, Orderly but Grim,’’ New
York Times, June 8, 1932, 1.
40. Dickson and Allen, Bonus Army, 176.
41. Ibid., 174.
42. Ibid., 193.
43. Rexford Guy Tugwell, The Brains Trust (New York: Viking, 1968),
357–59.
54
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
0
200,000
400,000
600,000
Unemployment Real GDP
800,000
1,000,000
1,200,000
0 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 1940
5
10
15
20
25
3. GDP and Unemployment. Unemployment as a percentage of the
civilian labor force, measured on the vertical axis, and real GDP in
millions of 1996 dollars, measured on the right vertical axis.
Chapter 4
Reflation and Relief
When Franklin Delano Roosevelt took the oath of office as
president for the first time on March 4, 1933, every moving part in
the machinery of the American economy had evidently broken.
Banks, farms, factories, and trade had all failed.
Roosevelt right away began working to repair finance, agriculture,
and manufacturing, though he would give less attention to
overseas economic affairs. As Isaiah Berlin afterward noted,
Roosevelt’s ‘‘great social experiment was conducted with an
isolationist disregard of the outside world.’’ The New Deal worked
to solve the current crisis and prevent future catastrophe in
America alone, by American methods, ‘‘with a minimum of
relationship with the outside world, which [Berlin continued] was
indeed to some degree part of American political tradition.’’ 1
The Roosevelt agenda grew by experiment: the parts that worked,
stuck, no matter their origin. Indeed, the program got its name by
just that process: Roosevelt used the phrase ‘‘new deal’’ when
accepting the Democratic nomination for president, and the press
liked it. 2 The ‘‘New Deal’’ said that Roosevelt offered a fresh start,
but it promised nothing specific: it worked, so it stuck.
The administration’s policies to revive the money and credit of the
country together with its policies to relieve the immediate misery of
56
the American people ranked among the earliest and most enduring
successes of the New Deal. From the time of their initial
implementation in 1933 to the mobilization for war production in
1940, with the sole exception of the recession of 1937–38, the
American economy grew at averaged rates of around 8 to 10
percent a year. Likewise, unemployment fell dramatically from its
unconscionable 1932 peak. If merely curing the immediate
Depression were the only New Deal goal, its policies of relief and
reflation might, pursued vigorously and consistently, have proved
sufficient to the task, and their evident success had much to do
with the electorate’s willingness to support Roosevelt.
Roosevelt began by rescuing the banks. Two days after taking
office, he declared the nation’s banks must stop transactions in
gold, thus shutting them down, and he asked Congress to ratify his
action. Congress complied with the Emergency Banking Act on
March 9, which affirmed Roosevelt’s action, and appointed a
receiver with the power to reorganize banks if necessary. In
addition, the law empowered RFC to buy bank stock and allowed
the Federal Reserve System greater latitude in issuing currency,
both measures meant to make money more readily available. 3
Three days later, Roosevelt spoke to the nation over the radio for
the first of a series of ‘‘fireside chats,’’ in which he explained how the
banks worked, what he had done, and that ‘‘I hope you can see
from this elemental recital of what your Government is doing that
there is nothing complex, or radical, in the process.’’ 4 The next day,
March 13, banks began to open. Ultimately, the bill allowed about
half the country’s banks to reopen without qualification, a quarter
to reopen with some limits on withdrawals, a fifth to undergo
reorganization, and required the remainder—about 1,000 banks—
to close up shop. 5
The bank holiday set a recurring pattern for New Deal legislation.
The president would take swift action of sometimes dubious
constitutionality—in this case, Roosevelt rested his authority for
bank closures on the not transparently applicable Trading with the
57
R e fl a tio
n a n d R e lie
f
Enemy Act, passed during World War I and giving the president
powers during war. 6 Congress would quickly comply, often adding
to the bill measures that went further even than Roosevelt
originally anticipated—in this case, not only did Congress amend
the Trading with the Enemy Act to include peacetime emergencies,
it added banking law that drew on preceding state action and on
measures legislators had contemplated during the Hoover
administration. The president would sell the action, with the
charming combination of his aristocratic accent and plain
language, to the American public—in this case, saying simply, ‘‘ We
had a bad banking situation.’’ Roosevelt would also go beyond
simple folksiness into a teacherly explanation of the circumstances
and his policy, trying truly to explain the technical details of the
emergency and his response. However precipitous Roosevelt’s
4. Franklin D. Roosevelt seated behind a microphone during a
Fireside Chat in 1937.
58
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
action, he aimed at fundamentally conservative goals. As one of his
advisors, Raymond Moley, later wrote, as a result of the bank
holiday, ‘‘Capitalism was saved in eight days.’’ 7 Or at least a part of
capitalism, anyway. With achievements like this, the crisis in which
the country found itself would incrementally improve, earning the
administration a degree of credibility and perhaps the latitude for
further and lasting reform of the American economic system.
The reform came three months later in the Banking Act of 1933,
which owed almost nothing to Roosevelt. The law increased the
power of the Federal Reserve Board to regulate banking, divided
the banks that dealt with public depositors from those that
invested on Wall Street, and—against Roosevelt’s initial
judgment—established a temporary Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation (FDIC) through which the federal government stood
behind the ordinary American’s savings. The president worried
that the government would one day find itself forced to pay out too
large a sum for failed banks, but he accepted the plan—wisely, as it
turned out: under FDIC bank failures dropped by an order of
magnitude. 8 In 1935 Congress gave FDIC a permanent charter.
In its conservative, capitalism-saving aspect, the story of banking
reform adumbrates the later, larger story of the New Deal;
throughout, Franklin Roosevelt emphasized his economic
orthodoxy. In his radio address he explained that although the
Federal Reserve Board could issue more currency now, this
currency would rest on a sound basis. ‘‘This currency is not
fiat currency,’’ he declared. Yet even as he assured the voters,
and perhaps himself, of his staid intentions with respect to the
currency, he was moving in the opposite direction.
Ever since the 1890s, when the Democratic Party first began to
shift from its historic support for limited government, and when,
under the leadership of William Jennings Bryan, it began to stand
for the ordinary man against the great manufacturing
corporations, the Democrats also had a soft spot for soft money.
59
R e fl a tio
n a n d R e lie
f
Bryan stood for the farmer and the worker against the gold
standard, adherence to which was driving down the price of
agricultural commodities. Instead, Bryan argued, the country
should coin silver, inflating—or, properly, reflating—the currency
and relieving the downward pressure on prices. Forty years on, the
situation looked similar. Roosevelt not only depended on the farm
vote, but like Bryan and many if not most Americans, he thought
fondly of the nation’s long-vanishing family farms, and he hoped to
provide them the same relief that Bryan had proposed: more
money in circulation, higher dollar prices for their produce, and an
easier time repaying their debts. As he said in January 1933, ‘‘If the
fall in the price of commodities cannot be checked, we may be
forced to an inflation of our currency. This may take the form of
using silver as a base, or decreasing the amount of gold in the
dollar. I have not decided how this inflation can be best and most
safely accomplished.’’ 9
To inflate the currency, Roosevelt would have to cut the dollar
loose from gold, to which it, like the other major currencies of the
world, had been anchored. Under the gold standard, countries, in
theory, agreed to keep their currencies convertible to gold by
maintaining only so much money in circulation as their gold
reserves warranted. If their gold reserves fell—because, perhaps,
their creditors demanded payment—they would have to use their
central banks to reduce the money supply within their economies,
lest their currencies drop in value. As early as 1929, after the drop-
off in U.S. overseas lending and the rise in protective tariffs, the
requirement of keeping their currencies in proportion to their gold
supplies became too burdensome to a number of Latin American
and European countries. The 1931 failure of Credit-Anstalt, a
major Austrian bank, led to worldwide gold withdrawals, including
from the financial capital of the world, London. By September,
Britain had to withdraw itself from the gold standard. To bankers,
politicians, and other people who regarded the British empire as
solid and the gold standard as the foundation of its solidity, this
abandonment looked dire indeed.
60
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
In the face of this crisis, the Federal Reserve System raised interest
rates to discourage gold withdrawals from the United States.
Investors would see the higher rates and know, first, that they
could realize a higher return in America, and so keep their money
there, and second, that by making money more expensive to
borrow, the Federal Reserve meant to reduce the amount in
circulation, thus defending the dollar’s convertibility to gold. 10
Satisfactory though this strategy might prove to proponents of the
gold standard, it made money more expensive at a time when many
Americans desperately needed it cheaper. Easier money would
have meant more borrowing, more investment, and more jobs. But
the system’s bankers chose the gold standard over relief of
domestic troubles. Hoover made a joint announcement with the
French prime minister, Pierre Laval, in support of the gold
standard. American central bankers stood with their French
counterparts, who ‘‘consider[ed] the convertibility into gold not as
a servitude which has grown out of date, but as a necessary
disciplinary requirement. We see in it the only efficient guarantee
for security of contracts and for the morality of business
transactions.’’ 11
The 1933 Emergency Banking Act only temporarily cut the dollar’s
tether to gold. But in April, Roosevelt issued an executive order
preventing Americans from holding gold, except in small amounts,
and required them to turn their gold in to Federal Reserve
Banks in return for other currency. A few weeks later the
president let it be known, the New York Times reported, that
‘‘He foresaw . . . a situation arising where the radical element
in Congress . . . might . . . enact legislation of a revolutionary
character’’—perhaps to coin silver. To prevent this radical action,
Roosevelt allowed that ‘‘some sort of inflation might be helpful,’’
but perhaps better that he provide it himself rather than leave it to
Congress. 12
It became clear that the temporary escape from gold
might represent a new policy entirely. Under the Thomas
Amendment to the Agricultural Adjustment Act of May 12,
Congress allowed the president to fix the price of the dollar in gold.
61
R e fl a tio
n a n d R e lie
f
The dollar price of gold rose from its previous rate of $20.67 per
ounce to $30 per ounce. At the end of the summer, Roosevelt
began using RFC to buy gold at steadily higher prices. In a
fireside chat he announced, ‘‘My aim in taking this step is to
establish and maintain continuous control. This is a policy, not
an expedient! . . . We are thus continuing to move toward a
managed currency.’’ 13
In January 1934, Congress passed the
Gold Reserve Act, upon which Roosevelt fixed the price of gold
at $35 per ounce and took title of all the monetary gold in the
country. 14
The New Deal Congresses reacted to the widespread belief that the
bankers and brokers had caused the crash by giving Roosevelt
and his appointees extraordinary discretion to manipulate money
and banking, which if they had used recklessly might have
damaged the financial industry and the American economy. In
addition to the Emergency Banking Act and the Thomas
Amendment, the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 created the
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), broadly empowered
to regulate Wall Street by preventing traders’ misuse of insider
information. 15 The Banking Act of 1935 put control of the Federal
Reserve System in its board of presidentially appointed governors,
rather than in the system’s bankers. 16
Roosevelt managed to avoid
some of the potential opprobrium from business by judicious use of
power and by careful appointments, as when he reassured nervous
bankers by appointing veteran trader Joseph Kennedy the first
chairman of SEC. Within a few years businessmen gave only SEC
among New Deal regulatory agencies a greater than 50 percent
approval rating. 17
Aside from his political judgment, luck also blessed Roosevelt in
the use of his broad new powers. When the dollar fell in value, the
price of farm commodities, particularly cotton and grain, rose,
making it easier for indebted farmers to pay their creditors. 18
Perhaps more importantly, overseas investors began selling their
gold for dollars. Gold began flowing into the United States. The
62
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
United States had always enjoyed a peculiar position among
nations, securely connected to Europe through economic and
cultural ties, yet geographically and politically distinct. And now
this position began to benefit Americans as political upheaval in
Europe, coupled with first the threat and then the actuality of war,
increased the golden inflow through the 1930s. This gold put
American banks in a much more stable position, increasing the
money supply to the American economy. Banks began offering
credit at lower interest rates, making it possible for businessmen to
consider borrowing and investing in those aspects of their
enterprises that would create more jobs, which helped account for
the drop in unemployment during Roosevelt’s term. 19
The Roosevelt administration did more than its predecessor to
revive American banking, and its efforts evidently succeeded. But
the New Deal’s financial policies—however plainly Roosevelt
explained them over the radio—dealt with matters far removed
from ordinary Americans’ experience. Later laws did more to put
the federal government into the business of backing citizens’
investments—the federal government insured mortgages and
through dedicated agricultural agencies worked to secure farmers’
credit. But in 1933, Roosevelt’s policymakers knew they must reach
ordinary Americans more directly and quickly than they could by
saving banks and stabilizing credit. During the Roosevelt
administration, the federal government of the United States began
for the first time to offer substantial direct aid to the nation’s
unemployed. These relief measures emerged piecemeal from
political compromises, rather than from blueprints, and changed
considerably over the years. The last year of Hoover’s
administration brought the beginnings of a federal relief program,
but it came grudgingly and too slow: the Emergency Relief and
Construction Act of 1932 allowed RFC to loan up to $300 million
to states for relief. But the program, offering as it did loans rather
than grants, and going through existing state bureaucracies,
accomplished little and certainly came too late to lift Hoover in
public opinion. 20
63
R e fl a tio
n a n d R e lie
f
Early in the New Deal, congressmen found it easy to identify young
unemployed men as especially worth their attention. Young
workers, with fewer skills and experience, found themselves out of
work more often than workers at the peak of their powers. Yet by
virtue of their youth they represented great promise. Young men, by
the standards of the era, stood to become future heads-of-household
and family providers. Contrariwise, if nobody did anything to help
them soon, young men were most likely to leave their communities,
becoming tramps or hoboes, posing a threat to social order.
Thus on March 31, 1933, within the first month of the Roosevelt
administration, Congress created the Civilian Conservation Corps
(CCC), which it chartered initially to provide work for men
between the ages of 18 and 35 (inclusive). If single, healthy,
unemployed, an American citizen, and a member of a family on
relief, a young man could join the CCC, sign over a significant
chunk of his wages to his family, and head out for a camp,
organized and run by the War Department, somewhere in the
American countryside. The Agriculture and Interior Departments
had a list of jobs to preserve the nation’s crops and forests. Floods
and forest fires needed preventing and fighting; pests required
eradication; roads and bridges, fences and firebreaks all wanted
building. A few hundred thousand of the country’s young men,
culled from the unemployment rolls and kept to around two and a
half thousand camps, supervised by soldiers, seemed just the
solution for these problems. 21
Americans might have worried about CCC’s quasi-military
qualities and the potential for indoctrination of the nation’s youth
in government-run camps. But the boys generally served short
stints—initial enrollment lasted six months, and legislation later
limited enrollment to two years. And as a small, closely focused
program justified by generally agreed-upon beliefs identifying
young men as especially worthy of the government’s resources,
CCC enjoyed a comparative freedom from criticism not extended
to other New Deal relief programs. 22
64
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
In May, Congress passed the Federal Emergency Relief Act, which
created the Federal Emergency Relief Administration (FERA),
devoting another $500 million of RFC’s money to grants, rather
than loans, to the states to support relief. Half the money would go to
states based on how much money they themselves spent; the other
half relied on the discretion of FERA’s administrator. Roosevelt
appointed Harry Hopkins, a rail-thin, chain-smoking social worker
who ran New York State’s relief efforts when Roosevelt was
governor, to head the agency. Hopkins set up a desk in a corridor of
RFC’ s offices and began handing out money to the states. 23
In June, Congress appropriated $3.3 billion, which became the
purse of the Public Works Administration (PWA). As the nation’s
gross domestic product for 1933 amounted only to $56.4 billion,
this sum amounted to an extraordinary 5.9 percent of the
American economy’s overall size that year. 24
Roosevelt appointed
his secretary of the interior, Harold Ickes, to run PWA. Originally a
Republican from Chicago, Ickes used his vast resources carefully,
treating PWA often only as a financing agency for local
governments, which had to design, authorize, and appropriate
most of the funds to back a major project if they wished to qualify
for Ickes’s largesse.
In consequence of Ickes’s care and Hopkins’s comparatively small
budget, the early relief effort, even though it earned headlines,
made scarcely a dent in the problem of unemployment. Watching
as the nation headed into another Depression winter, Hopkins
urged on Roosevelt the creation of a new agency, one that would
allow him to bypass state officials and employ people directly.
Roosevelt obliged by creating the Civil Works Administration
(CWA) and charging Hopkins with hiring four million Americans,
which he did, by January 1934. Mindful of Americans’ attitudes
toward public assistance, Hopkins meant CWA to dignify relief by
providing work to employees, rather than handouts to clients.
Soon CWA workers were fixing up city halls, docks, and public
roads, all on the federal government’s payroll.
65
R e fl a tio
n a n d R e lie
f
If to Americans of later generations PWA, FERA, CCC, CWA,
and RFC, along with their many sibling New Deal agencies,
made up a bewildering alphabet soup of bureaucracies,
Americans in the 1930s had reason to know which was which.
They knew RFC was Hoover’s bank-saving agency (now become
the pot from which many New Deal agencies scooped a portion),
that CCC enrolled their sons and brothers to protect the
American land, that PWA would soon build a school, hospital,
bridge, port, causeway, or airport (although it had not begun yet),
and that CWA got them through the bitter, record-setting cold of
winter in 1933/34. 25
Likewise, the money Congress appropriated for various New Deal
programs often later seemed like so many variously sized drops in
an ocean of fiscal red ink. In 1932, the federal government spent
only about half what the state and local governments spent. By the
eve of World War II, the New Deal had more than doubled federal
spending. All the while lawmakers, and especially the president,
fretted over the millions and billions they added to the federal
budget. 26
Partly for this reason, CWA did not last. Its expense, and even the
gratitude with which Americans greeted it, made Roosevelt
nervous. He did not like spending more money than the
government took in, nor did he like letting Americans rely directly
on the federal government for relief programs. In his skittishness
Roosevelt conceded the necessity of a national work relief
program, but he did not want it to ‘‘ become a habit with the
country.’’ And before spring he had ordered Hopkins to fire his
four million workers, in the vain hope that the brief program had
provided enough of a push. 27
Despite the phased demobilization
of CWA, staggered to prevent too many people from going on the
market at once, it left people writing Hopkins plaintively for
‘‘some kind of aid a job any where any kind of work’’ and
administrators complaining that a public work half done was
worse than one never begun. 28
66
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Despite Roosevelt’s nerves, he liked the idea of work relief better
than handing out money. So when by the end of 1934 the
Depression still had not lifted, his administration began designing
a new program of work relief. Americans of the 1930s knew that
work relief cost more than direct relief. Simply paying money to the
poor was cheaper than setting up a bureaucracy to plan projects to
employ the poor. But pride and their morality led them to prefer
the costlier course, which allowed desperate Americans the dignity
of meaningful work.
The spring of 1935 brought a new Emergency Relief Appropriation
Act, giving the president nearly $5 billion for relief projects
including highways, conservation, irrigation, electrification,
housing, sanitation, reforestation, flood control, and indeed almost
any conceivable public good. 29
Roosevelt used the act to set up the
Works Progress Administration (WPA), which took over from
FERA and became Hopkins’s new brief. With WPA, the New Deal
government frankly and fully entered the business of hiring the
American people to end the Great Depression. Whereas PWA and
FERA mostly respected the existing federal structure of the United
States, by spending money from the national treasury through
state and local governments, WPA repeated and magnified the
brief CWA experience, making it an ongoing and central feature of
New Deal government.
With WPA, Hopkins once more hired millions, and put them to
work building hospitals, schools, playgrounds, and airports. This
agency employed artists and writers and actors to ply their trade. It
built roads and public housing. but it also drew immediate
criticism for spending public money to pay idle hands to do useless
work poorly. The purpose and structure of the agency not only
guaranteed it would get these complaints, it further guaranteed
that such critiques would have some truth in them. Roosevelt
meant WPA to hire as many people as quickly as possible to reduce
unemployment as much as possible. To really reduce
unemployment, its projects could not do what private enterprise
67
R e fl a tio
n a n d R e lie
f
was doing, or what local governments were doing; otherwise, the
federal government would simply be substituting WPA jobs for
already existing jobs and would thus not reduce unemployment. As
a result, WPA jobs might well look like the sort of project that
would not ordinarily get done—make-work, or boondoggles, or
(less ungenerously) the comforts of civilization.
Moreover, WPA offered a temptation for at least mild political
corruption. Hopkins had money to give out to local officials,
mayors who normally had to beg indifferent or hostile state
legislators for support. Now someone in Washington, someone
with funds, wanted their friendship. Big-city mayors who governed
large voting populations had an especially good claim on WPA’s
attention.
Congress responded to concerns about WPA’s possible political
uses by drawing ever-narrower boundaries around the agency,
boundaries that by themselves indicate what worried or offended
people about the agency. From 1936, illegal immigrants could not
work for WPA. From 1937, WPA workers had to accept private-
sector offers or be released from the agency. From 1938, WPA
employees had to supply a quarterly statement of outside
earnings, if any; veterans had first right to a WPA job, then
American citizens, then immigrants who had declared an intent to
become citizens. Other immigrants could not apply. From 1939,
workers could stay on the rolls for only eighteen months unless
recertified as needy, and WPA workers had to be American
citizens. 30
While Congress tried to prevent the political use of WPA, criticism
of its projects backfired. Public works that might look extravagant
at first glance (a $25,000 dog pound for Memphis, Tennessee, for
example) turned out to serve a useful purpose, reducing the
number of dog bites and treatments for rabies in the city. 31
Each
project proved popular in its own community. And WPA built a
great many projects.
68
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
On the whole, WPA embodied new assumptions about earnings.
It defined a ‘‘security wage,’’ which though minimally adequate
was often higher than private bosses wanted to pay, and its
paychecks came with a regularity previously unknown to workers
accustomed to seasonal or cyclical unemployment. It contributed
legitimacy to the once unorthodox idea that Americans deserved a
certain degree of job security and a minimum standard of living as
an essential part of their dignity. Americans, WPA’s ‘‘security
wage’’ suggested, ought to earn a wage sufficient to provide them
more than subsistence, enough to allow them pride and
independence from their employers. 32
A 1939 Institute of Public Opinion poll found that, when asked to
name ‘‘the worst thing the Roosevelt Administration has done,’’
23 percent of Americans picked ‘‘Relief and the WPA,’’ making it
the most unpopular New Deal measure. Given the American
prejudice against federal relief and the potential for political abuse,
it was scarcely surprising. The same poll found that, when asked to
name ‘‘the greatest accomplishment of the Roosevelt
administration,’’ 28 percent of Americans picked ‘‘Relief and the
WPA,’’ making it the most popular New Deal measure. Given the
variety and local popularity of relief projects, this was unsurprising
too. That 5 percent margin on an issue central to the New Deal
made more than enough political difference to the Democrats. 33
Between the immediate effects of relief, which gave Americans
not just something to spend, but the ability to regard themselves
again as decent and productive citizens, and the longer-term
effects of reflation, which quietly began rebuilding the
private-sector economy, the Roosevelt administration might
have had an adequate strategy for fighting the Depression,
although for the government really to pull the country out of
its economic slough would require a more vigorous pursuit of
both policies. But its policymakers wanted to accomplish
something further and different than the mere conclusion of
a crisis: they wanted to make sure the Depression could
69
R e fl a tio
n a n d R e lie
f
not happen again. To do so, they expected to change the American
political economy forever.
Notes
1. Isaiah Berlin, ‘‘President Franklin Delano Roosevelt,’’ in The Proper
Study of Mankind: An Anthology of Essays, ed. Henry Hardy and
Roger Hausheer (London: Chatto and Windus, 1997), 629.
2. William E. Leuchtenburg, Franklin D. Roosevelt and the New Deal,
1932–1940 (New York: Harper Torchbooks, 1963), 8.
3. James Stuart Olson, Saving Capitalism: The Reconstruction
Finance Corporation and the New Deal, 1933–1940 (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1988), 30.
4. First Fireside Chat (Banking), May 12, 1933, consulted online
2/27/2007, www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid¼14540. 5. Peter Fearon, War, Prosperity, and Depression: The U.S. Economy,
1917–1945 (Lawrence: University Press of Kansas, 1987), 219.
6. Samuel Anatole Lourie, ‘‘The Trading with the Enemy Act,’’
Michigan Law Review 42, no. 2 (1943).
7. Raymond Moley, After Seven Years (New York: Harper and
Brothers, 1939), 155.
8. Milton Friedman and Anna Jacobson Schwartz, A Monetary
History of the United States, 1867–1900 (Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1963), 437.
9. Barrie A. Wigmore, ‘‘Was the Bank Holiday of 1933 Caused by a Run
on the Dollar?,’’ Journal of Economic History 47, no. 3 (1987): 743.
10. Lester V. Chandler, American Monetary Policy, 1928–41 (New
York: Harper and Row, 1971), 177.
11. Ibid., 168.
12. ‘‘President’s Action Forced by Events,’’ New York Times,
4/20/1933, 1.
13. Chandler, American Monetary Policy, 276.
14. ‘‘President’s Statement of Action under the New Law,’’ New York
Times, 2/1/1934, 12; Gold Reserve Act is 48 Stat. 337; Friedman
and Schwartz, Monetary History, 465.
15. 48 Stat. 881.
16. Richard H. Timberlake, Monetary Policy in the United States: An
Intellectual and Institutional History (Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1993), 283.
70
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
17. Ralph F. de Bedts, ‘‘The First Chairmen of the Securities and
Exchange Commission: Successful Ambassadors of the New Deal
to Wall Street,’’ American Journal of Economics and Sociology 23,
no. 2 (1964): 176.
18. Christina D. Romer, ‘‘Why Did Prices Rise in the 1930s?,’’ Journal
of Economic History 59, no. 1 (1999): 174.
19. Romer, ‘‘What Ended the Great Depression?,’’ Journal of Economic
History 52, no. 4 (1992): 757.
20. Lewis Meriam, Relief and Social Security (Washington, DC:
Brookings Institution, 1946), 346.
21. Ibid., 434–42. Also Neil M. Maher, Nature’s New Deal: The
Civilian Conservation Corps and the Roots of the American
Environmental Movement (New York: Oxford University Press,
2007).
22. Meriam, Relief and Social Security, 441–42.
23. Leuchtenburg, Franklin D. Roosevelt, 120–21.
24. Historical Statistics of the United States, Millennial Edition
Online, series Ca74.
25. Leuchtenburg, Franklin D. Roosevelt and the New Deal, 122.
26. Historical Statistics of the United States, Millennial Edition
Online, series Ea18.
27. Leuchtenburg, Franklin D. Roosevelt and the New Deal, 122.
28. Bonnie Fox Schwartz, The Civil Works Administration, 1933–
1934: The Business of Emergency Employment in the New Deal
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1984), 234.
29. Meriam, Relief and Social Security, 354–56.
30. Ibid., 380–82.
31. Jason Scott Smith, Building New Deal Liberalism: The Political
Economy of Public Works, 1933–1956 (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2006), 149.
32. Meriam, Relief and Social Security, 385.
33. ‘‘Relief Top Issue, Survey Indicates,’’ New York Times, 6/4/
1939, 27.
71
R e fl a tio
n a n d R e lie
f
Chapter 5
Managing Farm and Factory
The New Deal’s earliest efforts to rewrite the rules of the United
States’ political economy included two major agencies to centralize
the planning of American production. Both efforts had more to do
with ambitions dating back to World War I than with responses to
the current crisis. And major components of both efforts failed
politically, but in their failure they pointed the way to a different
policy for preserving American capitalism.
If American money and banking policy put the United States on
the road to recovery within the first year of the Roosevelt
administration, it did little to help stabilize the world economy.
Indeed, as American monetary policy brought gold into the United
States, other countries felt pressure as their money supplies
dwindled. Roosevelt made it amply clear in his first year that he
could spare no thought for other countries as long as the American
situation remained so dire. In the summer of 1933 he scuttled the
international London Economic Conference by sending the
message, ‘‘The sound internal economic system of a Nation is a
greater factor in its well being’’ than anything the conference could
decide. 1 The peoples of the rest of the world would have each to
find their own route out of the crisis.
Some countries left the gold standard and began groping their own
way back to prosperity, in some cases by establishing exclusive
72
trade relations within their old colonial empires. Everywhere,
falling commodity prices hit farmers cruelly hard, and many
colonized countries had few major occupations besides farming.
Colonies, as ever, found themselves at the mercy of their imperial
masters. Latin American countries sought bilateral trade
arrangements to ensure purchases, Brazil offering coffee for
German machinery and Argentina selling beef to Britain.
As the crisis continued, political parties gained support by
proposing radically new systems of social organization. Fascist and
Communist movements gathered strength by promising various
forms of state socialism that would control national economies and
restore stability. Anti-imperialist movements arose to promise
independence to beleaguered farmers in the colonized world. 2
Everywhere, people hurt by the Depression sought some new form
of society immune to the ailments they faced. Or almost
everywhere: while the United States experienced some of the same
pressures, and sometimes its sufferers saw themselves in similar
terms to their peers in other countries, its radical movements
looked more traditional than novel. For example, one American
farm advocate declared that ‘‘American agriculture stands in just
the same subservient position to American industrialism that the
colonies occupied toward England a century and a quarter
earlier.’’ 3 But unlike their similarly economically subservient
colonial cousins, American farmers had representation in their
legislature—indeed, more representation than their numbers alone
would merit. In consequence, although the New Deal included
American experiments with economic planning, the tactics
adopted had less to do with radical responses to the immediate
crisis and more to do with the long history of farm grievances in
America.
By the time the United States sank into the Great Depression, the
country had already seen seventy years of nearly constant agitation
for federal action in favor of farmers. The legislation of the Civil
War era—principally the Homestead Act, the Pacific Railroad Act,
73
M a n a g in g F a rm
a n d F a c to ry
the Morrill Land Grant Act—encouraged Americans to go West in
the belief they would there find land on which they could settle into
single-family farming. The Reconstruction of the South after the
war had, albeit briefly, encouraged similar hopes of establishing
more single-family farms there. But small-time farmers in America
came soon to grief, suffering various combinations of aridity, debt,
infestation, and the consolidation of farmland in fewer, larger
holdings.
As one economic history of the United States has it, ‘‘Farmers are
always unhappy.’’ 4 ‘‘Always’’ may slightly overstate the case, but
even so, a variety of factors conspired to keep farmers on edge for
almost the entirety of the early twentieth century. Expensive and
innovative technologies made farming less a family pursuit and
more an industrial concern, with sound credit and efficiency
surpassing diligence and hardihood as the cardinal agrarian
virtues. The extension of transportation networks throughout the
world put farmers ever more obviously into competition with an
international market. Even as farmers faced more overseas
competition, they saw American tariff policy protect their fellow
citizens in manufacturing from the same pressures: for much of
this period, Congress favored using import taxes to prevent foreign
factories from selling their goods in the American market. Behind
the shield of the tariff, farmers saw, American manufacturers could
reduce production and raise prices without fear of international
competitors undercutting them. Meanwhile, the American people
moved in droves to cities, putting urban life and concerns at the
center of national debate and relegating agriculture to the margins.
While farming dwindled in economic and cultural importance,
farmers retained an outsized influence on national politics.
Because the United States Senate allocates legislators to states, not
to people, it overrepresents the less populated, more heavily
agrarian states of the nation. In consequence, farmers retained
great, though waning, influence in national politics even as they
became fewer in number. Further, Congress’s failure to adopt a
74
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
redistricting scheme after the 1920 Census—the first
count that showed more Americans living in cities than on
farms—guaranteed that rural Americans enjoyed better
representation in the House of Representatives than their
numbers warranted. 5
Into the 1920s, the effects of World War I rendered more acute the
chronic unhappiness of American farmers. During the war, the
United States shipped meat and grain to its allies, rationing them
at home on wheatless and meatless days. Thus deprived of their
traditional diet, Americans learned to eat more of the more
perishable fruits and vegetables, which also—Americans
found—kept them healthier. Also, the passage of laws prohibiting
manufacture and sale of alcoholic drinks reduced consumption
of grain. Thus demand for the staples of the American farm fell. 6
At the same time, farmers increased their harvests. While the
European powers waged war, American farmers rushed to feed
them, turning fields over to grain that might otherwise have lain
fallow or served as pasture. When the war ended, this extraordinary
demand ceased, but American farmers generally kept up their new
levels of productivity in the hope that prosperity might return. 7
With decreased demand and increased supply, farm prices fell.
They might have risen again if enough people left farming for other
pursuits and turned their land over to other uses. But many
American farmers wanted to remain farmers; they just wanted to
become better paid ones. So they banded together to lobby for
legislation restoring them to parity with their fellow countrymen in
the cities. They wanted to stay on the farm but live as comfortably as
people who worked in offices and factories. And increasingly, they
pointed to the era just before World War I as their golden mean,
when farm goods fetched what they saw as a fair price.
To return to that period of parity, farmers believed, they would
have to arrange their economic activity much as manufacturers
did, which meant controlling prices by curbing production. As
75
M a n a g in g F a rm
a n d F a c to ry
Henry A. Wallace, who would serve as secretary of agriculture
under Franklin Roosevelt, said in 1922, ‘‘It is no more wrong for
farmers to reduce production when prices are below cost of
production than it is for the United States Steel Corporation.’’ 8 To
Wallace and his allies, U.S. Steel symbolized all industrial
corporations that enjoyed advantages farmers did not: the tariff
protected manufacturers from foreign competition, and the scale
and scope of their operations let a central office reach decisions
that swayed the entire domestic market. Providing similar benefits
to agriculture meant first of all, as one advocate put it, ‘‘getting the
tariff to the farmer.’’ 9 But just blocking imports with a tariff
would have done no good, as American farmers were already
producing far more than the domestic market could consume. So
farmers needed further methods of gaining benefits similar to
those enjoyed by industry. In addition, farmers could only pine
for the centralized efficiency of major corporate offices: farm
producers were too many and too scattered to decide on
concerted activity.
In the early 1920s, farm advocates sketched a plan to skirt these
obstacles. George Peek, president of the Moline Plow Company in
Illinois, along with his business partner, Hugh S. Johnson,
realizing ‘‘you can’t sell a plow to a busted farmer,’’ developed an
idea that the farm bloc in Congress supported. Peek and Johnson
had both worked with the War Industries Board (WIB), the agency
that regulated American production during World War I, and they
believed their experience of managing an economy almost totally
sealed off from the world market would suit the country now.
A tariff, they thought, should block imports of farm goods, and a
government corporation should buy up any crop surplus and seek
to export it overseas. Farmers’ marketing associations would
work to coordinate domestic production. Peek’s plan became the
basis for the McNary-Haugen bills passed by Congress in the late
1920s and vetoed by President Calvin Coolidge on the grounds that
they would interfere too much with the free market and raise prices
for urban consumers. During his presidency, Herbert Hoover
76
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
sought a halfway position; even before the Crash he backed
Congress’s 1929 creation of a Federal Farm Board empowered to
loan money to farmers and to store excess crops, while encouraging
cooperative action in American agriculture. Like other Hoover
policies, it proved unequal to the Depression. 10
Other farm advocates pushed the McNary-Haugen idea further,
believing that tariff-like protections would not work well enough;
farmers had also to reduce their production. W. J. Spillman, an
economist working for the Department of Agriculture, developed a
plan of ‘‘domestic allotment.’’ Examining the domestic
consumption of (for example) wheat, the government would
determine the size of the domestic market for a commodity and
allot to each state and farm an appropriate share of this market.
Farmers producing their allotted share would receive market value
plus a bonus for their crop, and would have to take only market
value for any further production. 11 Milburn L. Wilson, a professor
of agricultural economics at Montana State College, promoted
domestic allotment aggressively, adding to the original idea and
urging it on farm association and broader business interests alike.
In its mature phases, the plan included self-financing provisions,
taxing the processors of a commodity (e.g., millers of grain into
flour) to pay for the allotments. Wilson promoted this plan to
Roosevelt’s campaign in 1932, and Roosevelt spoke favorably of an
interventionist farm policy in (as his advisor Raymond Moley said)
‘‘generalities too vague to require examination.’’ 12
The New Deal’s first major farm legislation, the Agricultural
Adjustment Act of 1933, reflected this long, if mixed, lineage.
Although it began by citing ‘‘the present acute emergency,’’ it
focused on farmers’ longer-standing complaints. It charged the
government with erasing the ‘‘severe and increasing disparity
between the prices of agricultural and other commodities, which
disparity has largely destroyed the purchasing power of farmers,’’
and it specifically pointed to the years just before the deranging
effects of World War I as the ideal of parity to which the country
77
M a n a g in g F a rm
a n d F a c to ry
should return. And in keeping with the New Deal preference for
vague generalities, it left the exact mechanism of the plan up to the
president but provided him the powers to reduce acreage under
production, to pay benefits for desirable harvests, and to tax
processors, all of which the domestic allotment idea required. 13
In
addition, the law exempted farm associations from antitrust
prosecution (making it possible for farmers to centralize their
decision-making) and made participation in its programs
voluntary.
Roosevelt’s appointments also reflected the heritage of his farm
policy: he named Wallace as secretary of agriculture and Peek as
head of the new Agricultural Adjustment Administration (AAA),
which would administer the production-control policy. Wilson
became head of AAA’s wheat section. 14 Differences of opinion split
these three longtime lobbyists for federal farm policy; Peek
preferred the use of marketing associations to reducing
production, Wilson wanted the domestic allotment plan as a step
to permanent acreage reduction, and Wallace told Wilson the
programs might work ‘‘if we are really going the route of state
socialism. And I am very much inclined to think that we really are
going that route.’’ 15 Coupled with the vagueness of the law and of
Roosevelt’s wishes, these divisions made an already difficult job
harder.
By the time AAA got under way in the spring of 1933, cotton
growers had already planted their crop. Seeing an abundance of
cotton already on hand, AAA asked growers to plow up their plants
in exchange for a fee, lest already low cotton prices fall further.
AAA agents spread out over hundreds of counties to persuade
farmers to dig up what they had just sown. They met problems
typical to any bureaucracy—they never had enough blank contract
forms where they needed them, and farmers complained about the
fairness of yield estimates, and an estimator’s freedom to indulge
his friends: ‘‘Our estamater sure did not give us a fair deal. . . . He
has pets.’’ 16
Checks for the plow-up often came late.
78
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Beyond these ordinary administrative difficulties, AAA met
problems specific to its agrarian mission. Mules long-trained to
avoid plowing up cotton plants balked when set to the task. Poor
weather prevented plow-ups in some places, and fair weather
discouraged farmers from plowing up a good crop in others.
Sometimes a sheriff had to send a tractor to enforce a plow-up
contract and charge the cost to the reneging farmer. 17 When plow-
up checks did come, landlords sometimes kept the payments from
tenants.
If the spectacle of a government destroying cotton when millions of
its people went without adequate clothing rankled, the spectacle of
that government destroying food in the midst of hunger positively
hurt. But to keep hog farming incomes up to parity, AAA officials
decided they had to slaughter millions of piglets, lest they in future
years fuel a glut. ‘‘That we should have . . . idle and hungry and ill-clad
millions on the one hand, and so much food and wool and cotton
upon the other that we don’t know what to do with it, this is an utterly
idiotic situation, and one which makes a laughing stock of our genius
as a people,’’ a Missouri farm leader claimed. 18
5. These men, members of the Civilian Conservation Corps, worked on
a poultry-raising farm in Jonesville, Virginia.
79
M a n a g in g F a rm
a n d F a c to ry
None of the farm policy’s architects really meant it to address the
nation’s ancient problems of rural poverty or the new problems of
the Great Depression. The law specifically aimed to erase the
inequality in purchasing power between countryside and city by
moving back to an imagined golden age, not forward to a brave
new world. Far from stimulating recovery by aiding the majority of
the nation’s buyers, its regressive processing taxes, passed on to
consumers, penalized urban buyers to benefit rural sellers.
Farmers mainly supported such policies: cotton growers lobbied to
have acreage reduction made compulsory once they realized that
nonparticipating farmers would derive the benefits of raised prices
without having to sacrifice a portion of their crop. In response
Congress passed the Bankhead Cotton Control Act of 1934, taxing
farmers on everything they sent for ginning over their quota. This
law required a referendum after its first year of operation, and in
the vote almost 90 percent of cotton-growers nationwide favored
its retention. 19
As John D. Black, an economist sympathetic to the domestic
allotment plan, noted in 1936, AAA took for its goal a relative rise
in farm incomes, not a rapid recovery from the Depression. For a
speedy recovery, a policy of raising farm incomes was generally
thought inferior to a policy of raising business profits, because
business profits meant more investment and higher wages for
more consumers. The best case one could make for AAA, Black
wrote, was ‘‘that it has given us a better recovery than would a
business-profits recovery, because . . . it has given us a better
distributed recovery’’—which was to say, a recovery better
distributed geographically, from city to farm, not a recovery better
distributed across classes. And even that case did not hold up
especially well, Black noted: while farm prices had risen, perhaps
two-thirds of their rise owed to drought and to the devaluation of
the dollar rather than to AAA action. 20
Moreover, as much as
farmers liked the rise in their prices, they lamented a simultaneous
rise in the prices of the goods they bought—a rise they attributed to
80
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
the New Deal’s other major economic management law, passed a
month after the agriculture act.
Industrial policy, like farm policy, drew on an established tradition
of centralizing authority to control prices, harking back to a
perceived golden era—this time during World War I, when the
government worked with business leaders on WIB to encourage
cooperation and command of production. While WIB veteran
George Peek went to head AAA, his old colleague from WIB days,
Hugh Johnson, helped create and run its industrial counterpart,
the National Recovery Administration (NRA).
At least since the great merger movements of the late nineteenth
century, major American businessmen regarded with suspicion
the principle of unfettered competition, which lowered the
prices they could get for their goods and services, sometimes
below the cost of production. Increasingly, they professed to
believe in an ‘‘ ‘economic right price,’ the ‘universal use’ of which,
through federal regulation, ‘would wholly and permanently
eliminate unfair price-cutting.’ ’’ 21
Businessmen thus faced similar
problems to American farmers, while enjoying certain natural
advantages. Manufacturing lent itself to centralized control more
easily than farming. Innovation in technology and techniques
permitted ever greater substitutions of machine and management
efficiency for employment of skilled labor, and thus put control
of the factory floor more securely into the hands of businessmen.
Indeed, perhaps the only obstacle (however low) to the utter
concentration of manufacturing was the federal antimonopoly
code.
WIB taught businessmen that with government cooperation,
instead of antagonism, they could control production to fix prices,
prevent strikes, and make a decent profit—all while appearing
patriotic. The Depression afforded them an opportunity to lobby
once more for such an emergency arrangement so they could
determine the right, higher price for their products.
81
M a n a g in g F a rm
a n d F a c to ry
The first business-government collaboration of the Depression had
been the Hoover-era ‘‘Buy Now’’ campaign. Journalists, politicians,
and other boosters implored the consumers who had driven the
boom of the 1920s to purchase their way back to prosperity. This
rhetorical campaign failed. In 1931 Business Week reported, ‘‘The
‘Buy Now’ idea seems to have faded out. . . . There appears to be
increasing doubt as to what buyers should use for money.’’ 22
By the
Roosevelt administration, it had become clear it would require
more than cheerleading to increase purchasing power. Roosevelt
asked his secretary of labor, Frances Perkins, if she could come up
with a way to provide labor unions a place in the industrial policy
for reducing competition. Perkins, America’s first female cabinet
member, had served in Roosevelt’s New York administration,
where she advocated minimum wage and maximum hours
legislation. Now she proposed the creation of industrial boards, on
which representatives of management, labor, and the government
might sit together. To participate in the policy, unions would also
need a right to organize, which Supreme Court cases had
questioned even after the 1914 Clayton Act exempted unions from
the antitrust laws. The American Federation of Labor (AFL)
defended the right to organize as a way to increase ‘‘buying
power.’’ 23
An economist with the brand-new AAA argued that the industrial
legislation had to perform a similar purpose to the farm law—to
promote not a speedier, but a better distributed, recovery: ‘‘I think
the act has got to do something about improving wages, about
improving labor conditions, about protecting collective bargaining
so that it will be in better balance, and so we will have a stimulation
of consumer interest and consumer buying.’’ 24
Like the Agricultural Adjustment Act, the industrial legislation
reflected its mixed origins. The National Industrial Recovery Act of
1933 included a variety of measures, including provision for public
works that allowed Roosevelt to create his work-relief agencies.
But its major provision allowed the creation of a more managed
82
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
industrial policy through boards like the ones Perkins had
envisioned, with management, labor, government, and consumer
representatives negotiating regulatory codes. Congress suspended
the antitrust laws to permit price-fixing among businesses for a
two-year period. It authorized the president to set, or to delegate
authority to set, codes of operation for industry that would
determine the basis for fair competition. In section 7a of Title 1, the
law required such codes to guarantee that
employees shall have the right to organize and bargain collectively
through representatives of their own choosing, and shall be free
from the interference, restraint, or coercion of employers of labor,
or their agents, in the designation of such representatives or in
self-organization or in other concerted activities for the purpose of
collective bargaining or other mutual aid or protection.25
Unions, business groups, and consumer advocates waited to see
what the President would do with his new powers.
Roosevelt launched NRA with warlike rhetoric, invoking ‘‘the great
cooperation of 1917 and 1918’’ as precedent, and named Hugh
Johnson, the former general, to run it, thus satisfying the
businessmen who looked fondly to WIB for inspiration. Johnson
created a martial symbol for NRA, a blue eagle clutching a gear and
a clawful of thunderbolts. He tried to mobilize consumers by
extending the wartime metaphor. ‘‘It is women in homes and not
soldiers in uniform who will this time save our country. . . . It is zero
hour for housewives.’’ 26
The price-raisers had the upper hand because executives of large
corporations had more control over their enterprises, greater
familiarity with the scale and scope of their operations, and a
good friend in Hugh Johnson. By the end of summer 1933, most
major industries had developed codes, while less than 10 percent
of the industries with NRA code-making authorities had a labor
member and even fewer had a consumer representative. Thus,
83
M a n a g in g F a rm
a n d F a c to ry
many of the codes resulted from negotiations between
businessmen and government officials, many of whom had
recently been businessmen themselves. As one observer
complained, NRA codes looked like ‘‘a bargain between business
leaders on the one hand and businessmen in the guise of
government officials on the other.’’ 27
Labor leaders discovered that
management could circumvent section 7a by creating company-
run unions. Workers began to complain that prices were going up,
but not wages. NRA, which looked every day more like what critics
called an ‘‘Old Deal’’ organization, repeated the Hoover-era ‘‘Buy
Now’’ campaign, to the same response: ‘‘What with?’’ as one farmer
asked. 28
NRA also deeply vexed some owners of smaller businesses. Many
found themselves ill-equipped to deal with the bureaucratic
requirements of code compliance and unlikely to make themselves
heard against larger competitors in the code-making authorities.
The principal price-fixing measures of the codes catered to larger
businesses trying to prevent niche competitors from undercutting
them. And especially in the Depression, standing up for the little
guy offered an irresistible political opportunity, as Frances Perkins
observed: ‘‘You can always get sympathy by using the word
small. . . . With little industries you feel as you do about a little
puppy.’’ 29
In response NRA established a board to investigate such
complaints. Headed by the celebrity lawyer Clarence Darrow, the
study discovered ‘‘monopolistic practices’’ in seven of the eight
NRA industries it studied, and found that small businesses were
‘‘cruelly oppressed.’’ 30
By 1934, NRA had stalled amid criticism. Johnson resigned,
replaced by a committee. Early in 1935, an examination of NRA
found only two instances in which codes had been enforced against
business. With the two-year exemption from antitrust prosecution
nearly expired, the Senate defied Roosevelt, voting only a limited
extension of NRA. 31
Before the House could decide whether it
agreed, the Supreme Court declared NRA unconstitutional—but it
84
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
was already clear that in Roosevelt’s subsequent, privately
expressed opinion, NRA gave him ‘‘an awful headache’’ and some
of its policies had been ‘‘pretty wrong.’’ 32
Before long the Supreme Court would also strike down AAA. For
the Court, the two agencies similarly violated the Constitution:
they exerted an unprecedented and unauthorized coercive
executive power within states. As Henry Wallace had said, such
agencies edged toward ‘‘state socialism,’’ which it is fair to suppose
most Americans, even in that desperate crisis, regarded with
suspicion.
Shorn of their more statist, managerial elements, key parts of the
AAA and NRA survived as Congress reenacted them in law.
Inasmuch as neither program aimed at a swift recovery, but
tried instead to provide a different balance in the distribution of
American wealth and power—from city to countryside and from
management to labor and consumers—the policies enjoyed
considerable popularity among important Roosevelt
constituencies, representing aspects of the New Deal approach to
political economy that would last well beyond the Depression.
Notes
1. Lester V. Chandler, American Monetary Policy, 1928–41 (New York:
Harper and Row, 1971), 281.
2. Dietmar Rothermund, The Global Impact of the Great Depression
(London: Routledge, 1996), 107, 29.
3. Judith Goldstein, ‘‘The Impact of Ideas on Trade Policy: The Origins
of U.S. Agricultural and Manufacturing Policies,’’ International
Organization 43, no. 1 (1989): 35.
4. Susan Previant Lee and Peter Passell, A New Economic View of
American History (New York: W. W. Norton and Company, 1979),
301.
5. Zechariah Chafee Jr., ‘‘Congressional Reapportionment,’’ Harvard
Law Review 42, no. 8 (1929); Orville J. Sweeting, ‘‘John Q. Tilson
and the Reapportionment Act of 1929,’’ Western Political Quarterly
9, no. 2 (1956).
85
M a n a g in g F a rm
a n d F a c to ry
6. Theodore Saloutos, The American Farmer and the New Deal
(Ames: Iowa State University Press, 1982), 9.
7. Ibid., 5.
8. Ibid., 32.
9. Goldstein, ‘‘Impact of Ideas,’’ 43.
10. Keith J. Volanto, Texas, Cotton, and the New Deal (College Station:
Texas A&M University Press, 2005), 15 ff.
11. Ibid., 20.
12. William D. Rowley, M. L. Wilson and the Campaign for the
Domestic Allotment (Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 1970),
15; Saloutos, The American Farmer and the New Deal, 41; Volanto,
Texas, Cotton, 22.
13. 48 Stat. 31, 34–5.
14. Rowley, M. L. Wilson, 195.
15. Ibid., 138.
16. Volanto, Texas, Cotton, 45.
17. Ibid., 49.
18. Anthony J. Badger, The New Deal: The Depression Years, 1933–40
(London: Macmillan, 1989), 163.
19. Volanto, Texas, Cotton, 83.
20. John D. Black, ‘‘The Agricultural Adjustment Act and National
Recovery: Discussion,’’ Journal of Farm Economics 18, no. 2
(1936): 243.
21. Ellis W. Hawley, The New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly:
A Study in Economic Ambivalence (Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1966), 40.
22. Meg Jacobs, Pocketbook Politics: Economic Citizenship in
Twentieth Century America (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 2005), 96.
23. Hawley, New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly, 28.
24. Jacobs, Pocketbook Politics, 208.
25. 48 Stat. 195, 198.
26. Jacobs, Pocketbook Politics, 109.
27. Hawley, New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly, 57–62.
28. Ibid., 58, 93.
29. Ibid., 82.
30. Ibid., 96.
31. ‘‘Extension of NRA for Only 10 Months Voted By Senate,’’ New York
Times 5/15/1935, 1.
32. Frances Perkins, The Roosevelt I Knew (New York: Viking Press,
1946), 251.
86
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Chapter 6
Countervailing Power
From the first, and increasingly through the 1930s, New Dealers
asked the federal government to exercise new powers not mainly
for centralized planning or social welfare, but rather, as the
economist John Kenneth Galbraith would later say, ‘‘to give a
group a market power it did not have before.’’ Looking back from
1952, Galbraith noted that ‘‘the most important legislative acts of
the New Deal,’’ as well as those that ‘‘fueled the sharpest domestic
controversies,’’ were laws that enlisted the federal government in
‘‘the support of countervailing power.’’ 1
The idea of using the state to support private interests in the name
of countervailing power attracted New Dealers for two reasons.
First, it kept them on the side of American capitalism by stopping
short of state ownership or even regulation of business. Second, in
their understanding of history they were not the first American
lawmakers to use the federal government to support private
interests, they were simply the first to propose using the
government mainly to benefit groups other than the owners of
major corporations. As Senator Lewis Schwellenbach (D-WA)
said of the nation’s mythically government-free pioneer past,
‘‘Don’t let anyone tell you that government bounties were not being
given in those days. . . . The railroads got their sections of land in
each township. . . . Vast tracts of timber lands were available
for . . . the timber operators. . . . A protective tariff system was
87
maintained by which hidden taxes were removed from the pockets
of everyone who labored in industry and agriculture. . . . There were
[government] bounties galore. But the people who worked, and
who bought and consumed our products never got in on them.’’ 2
If those policies of the nineteenth-century Republican Party
succeeded in strengthening the original power within the
American industrial economy—the great banks and
manufacturing corporations of the Northeast—they left the rest
of the country relatively underdeveloped. Not coincidentally,
strong support for the New Deal came from the poorer South
and West, whose voters believed they benefited little from these
policies.
This historical legacy of lopsided regional riches made it happily
unnecessary for the Roosevelt administration to distinguish
between good politics and good policy: if they wanted to spend
money to even out economic development in the country and
create countervailing powers, they would spend it in the South and
the West, and on the industrial workers of the country.
Contrariwise, if they wanted to spend money to benefit the most
loyal and critical voters in the New Deal coalition, they would
spend federal money in the South and the West, and on the
industrial workers of the country. Politics and economics worked
together in the New Deal construction of countervailing power.
Franklin Roosevelt prided himself on inventing one way in which
the government could create countervailing power, which he called
the ‘‘yardstick’’ concept. During World War I, Roosevelt argued
while assistant secretary of the navy that the U.S. government
ought not to armor-plate all its own ships but rather should build a
small armor-plating plant and thus learn how much the process
should cost. The costs of the government-run plant would serve as
a measure of fair profit for private contractors, providing a
counterweight to the businessmen’s information on the cost of
production. The navy would then know what it ought to pay to give
88
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
contractors a fair, but not excessive, profit. Roosevelt remembered
this idea later. 3
At around the time Roosevelt was urging the government to enter
the armor-plating business, Washington was entering the
electricity business at Muscle Shoals in Alabama. There the
Tennessee River drops by 134 feet through thirty-seven miles of
rapids. And there the U.S. government built Wilson Dam,
providing hydroelectric power to factories producing nitrates for
fertilizer or explosives. 4 Before construction on the dam had quite
finished, the Harding administration proposed turning it over to
private management, and the Coolidge administration in its turn
supported this idea. Senator George Norris, a progressive
Republican of Nebraska and chairman of the Agriculture
Committee (which had charge of bills relating to fertilizer), blocked
the privatization plan and instead proposed expanding public
ownership of electrical production.
In the 1932 campaign Roosevelt stepped into this impasse between
privatization and public ownership, saying that a few government
power plants were ‘‘forever a yardstick to prevent extortion’’ by
private monopolies. After his inauguration he worked with Norris
to create the Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA), which would take
over Muscle Shoals and build other dams along the river,
extending government-provided power through much of the
South. 5
The law creating TVA listed among its several goals ‘‘the
agricultural and industrial development of said valley.’’ 6 Whereas a
generation before, the federal government under Republican
control lent itself to the development of the West by interstate
private railroad corporations, under Democratic control it now
pushed for the development of the South by interstate public
power corporations. But interstate and public did not here mean
distant or unresponsive: headquartered in Knoxville, Tennessee,
TVA devoted itself to working through local institutions and
89
C o u n te rv a ilin
g P o w e r
drumming up support for what its director, David Lilienthal, called
‘‘grass roots administration of federal functions.’’ If Americans
were going to adopt public ownership of electricity, Lilienthal
figured, they would have to do it locally—they would never support
and indeed, in the interest of democracy should never support,
national socialism, contrary to the ambitions of some planners and
the fears of their opponents. 7
Democratic politicians had long yearned to raise up the South from
its legacy of poverty and join it to the West as a balance to the
financial and industrial (and generally Republican) centers of the
Northeast and Midwest. But they had to circumvent white
southerners’ animosity to the federal government, whose Justice
Department and civil rights policies the white South had long
loathed. TVA’s campaign for locally controlled federal power helped
Democrats design a federal development policy white southerners
could stand. Repeatedly, southern cities held referenda in which
6. Civilian Conservation Corps boys weeding a Tennessee Valley
Authority nursery near Wilson Dam in Alabama.
90
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
citizens voted against the private monopolies and for public power,
with Lilienthal’s enthusiastic support. Energetic and well-funded
resistance to these votes came from private power corporations
owned by the holding company of Commonwealth and Southern,
which Wendell Willkie, a Democrat who supported Roosevelt in
1932, headed. TVA dampened Willkie’s affection for the
administration. While Willkie himself negotiated with TVA,
members of Commonwealth and Southern’s constituent companies
fought its expansion. Southern cities and TVA responded by
working to get PWA to build—or even merely to plan to build—
lines and plants to compete with, and render redundant, the
private power companies. Often PWA’s plans alone provided
enough federal leverage so the private power companies sold their
infrastructure and yielded to local, public control. 8
For much of the 1930s, Willkie’s companies kept TVA from
providing power to southern cities by suing and getting injunctions
from courts. Although higher courts eventually ruled in TVA’s
favor, the long judicial process forced Lilienthal to spend months
on the stump, contrasting TVA’s commitment to democracy and
local control to the private companies’ opposition to both. Under
such circumstances Lilienthal could credibly insist that though
TVA’s opponents might call it ‘‘soviet,’’ it was the power companies,
and not TVA, that favored the centralized, outside control of the
Tennessee River Valley.
TVA illustrated typical vices and virtues of the New Deal’s plans to
use federal leverage to empower existing groups. It brought
electrical power cheaply—at perhaps half the price Americans paid
to private companies—to people who never before had it, and its
success inspired private companies to try lower rates and larger
markets as well. TVA also inspired Roosevelt to try rural
electrification on a national scale, creating the Rural Electrification
Administration in 1935 with money from the relief act of that
year, to support the creation of rural power cooperatives. Like
TVA, REA not only opened service to new areas, it pressed private
91
C o u n te rv a ilin
g P o w e r
companies to see profit potential in markets they had hitherto
slighted. 9
In these respects the effort at generating electrical power for
countervailing constituencies worked, laying the foundations for
further economic development in regions sorely wanting it.
Inasmuch as it brought southern politicians and voters around to
the New Deal, it succeeded too. At the same time, TVA’s
commitment to respecting local institutions limited its support for
democracy: working through established southern structures
meant leaving the racial hierarchy of the South intact. TVA
fertilizer programs did not involve the historically black
agricultural colleges of the South, nor did its segregated workforce
look out of place in the land of Jim Crow. 10
The New Deal worked to develop the West, too. Critics of the
administration’s motives pointed out that the swing states of the
West, much more politically changeable than the Northeast or
South, received a disproportionate share of the New Deal’s dollars.
Although PWA officials responded that more than a fair share of
their budget went to the much longer settled and more developed
states east of the Mississippi, it remained the case that on a per
capita basis PWA money went much farther in the sparsely
populated West. Likewise, if the New Deal were in the business of
buying votes, western states had more electoral votes per capita to
offer.
Suspicions that the Roosevelt administration was buying the
West’s allegiance proved weakly founded. These states had a lot of
land and needed many miles of roads: if the federal government
were going to spend solely on the basis of need, it would spend
more money per capita on roads out West. Further, the West had
plenty of projects, particularly for hydroelectric power, already
planned and ready for funding. With so much land capable of
sustaining so many more people, paying for these projects in the
West looked like a good investment. Finally, the federal
92
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
government owned disproportionate shares of land in western
states—more than 80 percent of Nevada, for example—which
made it cheaper and easier to build projects there. 11
Just as spending money to develop the South made economic sense
because it meant tapping the potential that slavery and its legacy
had corked, spending money on the West made economic sense
too: it meant making way for the denser settlement of a potentially
much richer region. If New Deal development led also to
environmental spoliation, if it extended the American industrial
system indiscriminately, if it failed to disturb racial impediments to
democracy (WPA helped intern Japanese-Americans in the West
during World War II), or if it appeared suspiciously political, it also
looked like a sound investment. The construction of public works
under a policy of development raised up these historically
underdeveloped regions as countervailing powers to the older,
richer, and historically Republican Northeast. These policies also
represented the most redistributive policies of the New Deal:
although the Roosevelt administration may have worked to
redistribute money and power geographically, it did not as directly
use the state to redistribute money and power across classes.
At least since Adam Smith made ability to pay his first maxim of
taxation, countries more comfortable with state action than the
United States of the 1930s provided market power to groups that
otherwise did not enjoy it by taxing people who had more wealth
and using the proceeds to provide goods to people who had less.
Despite the directness of this method, the New Deal did not use it.
Indeed, the Roosevelt administration retained the opposite tax
policy as established under Hoover in 1932, adding AAA
processing taxes to regressive federal excise taxes on liquor and
other goods deemed luxuries or vices. These taxes put a
disproportionate burden on those Americans least able to pay.
Even the Revenue Act of 1935, which resulted from Roosevelt’s
request for a ‘‘sound public policy of encouraging a wider
distribution of wealth,’’ touched so few people it looked like ‘‘a hell
93
C o u n te rv a ilin
g P o w e r
raiser, not a revenue raiser,’’ as a member of the House Ways
and Means committee claimed. 12
Believing that prospects for
recovery depended on businessmen’s investment, the Democrats
stuck with the less-visible excise taxes—polls showed that
Americans rarely considered these levies to qualify as taxes—
instead of raising income taxes on more Americans.
But the Roosevelt administration did work to redistribute wealth,
just not through tax policy. Instead it wanted the market to work
more equitably, to allot to workers and consumers higher wages
without government’s direct intervention. To achieve this end the
New Deal fostered the growth of worker and consumer
organizations empowered to bargain collectively, and therefore
more effectively, for a better deal in the marketplace. A simple
theory supported this policy: if business had grown ever more
organized and therefore efficient at cutting its cost, so should the
buyers of products and the sellers of labor also organize and learn
efficiency. In an instance of this theory’s implementation, NRA
promoted the organization of consumers and laborers.
Mild as toleration of a labor union’s right to exist may seem,
management fought it. In 1934, the country’s factories exploded in
strikes as corporations refused to recognize unions. Strikes shut
down entire cities. Roosevelt established the National Labor
Relations Board (NLRB) to settle disputes. Investigations showed
the managers of American industries had determined to abort
unions’ birth, using infiltration, threats, speedups, and, bluntest
instrument of all, the desperate job market: ‘‘Look out the
window,’’ employers said, in numerous variations in numerous
workplaces, ‘‘and see the men waiting in line for your job.’’ 13
John L. Lewis of the United Mine Workers famously told his men,
‘‘The President wants you to join a Union.’’ 14
Lewis exaggerated:
Roosevelt disliked promoting confrontation with businessmen
who would lead the country’s economic recovery and viewed
unions with mistrust. But as on other issues, congressmen of
94
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Roosevelt’s party pushed the president. Senator Robert Wagner
drafted a bill to create a permanent NLRB and specifically to
prevent the formation of company unions or the intimidation of
union organizers. The law not only required companies to bargain
with union representatives elected by workers but also instituted
a majority rule providing that if a majority of workers in a shop
voted for a union, that union would have the power to represent
the whole shop.
Wagner saw the law as a way to keep from investing the state
with too much power. ‘‘The National Labor Relations Board is the
only key to the problem of economic stability if we intend to rely
upon democratic self-help by industry and labor instead of
courting the pitfalls of an arbitrary or totalitarian state.’’ 15 Stronger
unions, though a bitter pill, might go down more easily with
middle-class voters than indefinitely increased federal authority
and spending. And as passed by Congress in July 1935, shortly after
the Supreme Court struck down the National Industrial Recovery
Act, the Wagner Act replaced NRA’s statist code-making
authorities with the philosophy of countervailing power,
attributing the economic crisis to the earlier absence of an effective
counterweight to business management:
The inequality of bargaining power between employees who do not
possess full freedom of association . . . and employers who are
organized in the corporate or other forms of ownership
association . . . tends to aggravate recurring business depressions by
depressing wage rates and reducing the purchasing power of wage
earners. . . . It is hereby declared to be the policy of the United States
to . . . eliminate these obstructions . . . by encouraging the practice
and procedure of collective bargaining.16
Now the president really did want American workers to join a
union—the law required it of him. And despite an unfriendly labor
market (the ready availability of unemployed workers impeded
unionization) Americans did join: In 1930, under a tenth of workers
95
C o u n te rv a ilin
g P o w e r
in manufacturing belonged to unions, while by 1940, more than a
third did; in mining, the rate of unionization over the same period
went from slightly over a fifth to just under three-quarters. Similar
increases characterized other sectors. 17 Given the rate of
unemployment, the rise in unionization as a countervailing force to
managerial power owes considerably to the shift toward legal
protection for unions, finally and extensively justified by the time of
the Wagner Act as a way to achieve a more equitable distribution
of wealth without increasing the power of the state.
Federal policy encouraged Americans to organize themselves not
only as producers but also as consumers. Upon signing the
National Industrial Recovery Act, Roosevelt declared, ‘‘A
Consumers Advisory Board will be responsible that the interests of
the consuming public will be represented’’ in NRA’s code-making
process. 18
The head of the Consumers’ Advisory Board , Mary
Harriman Rumsey, advertised her willingness to listen to the
ordinary American consumer. 19
Complaints poured in, along with
labels and other evidence of rising prices on milk, bread, and
similar staples.
Similarly, AAA invited the consumers into the producers’ sanctum.
Frederic Howe, a municipal reformer and New York
Commissioner of Immigration in the 1910s, became consumers’
counsel to AAA in the summer of 1933. Howe had the job of
preventing prices from rising much higher than the level necessary
for producers to recover the AAA processing tax. 20
His office began
producing Consumers’ Guide, which listed prices for staple
products in various American cities, showing how much over cost
the prices had risen. Like Rumsey, Howe invited consumers to
report price rises and especially sought discrepancies between
listed and actual prices. 21
Before long these in-house consumer voices began seeking outside
help. Rumsey appointed economists and activists for the project of
‘‘building a Consumers’ movement.’’ They hoped to establish
96
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
consumer councils around the country. Although the president’s
purported wish that Americans join labor unions did much more
to organize the workforce than the consumer movement did, the
New Deal’s call for Americans to join consumer unions also
produced a counterweight to managerial decisions and indeed to
the administration’s own policies. Ultimately, the consumer
movement the New Deal helped build and tie to its policies lobbied
to change those policies. In response to such complaints, NRA
hosted a ‘‘Field Day of Criticism’’ that revealed widespread
consumer dissatisfaction with its work. One of NRA’s in-house
consumer advocates, Leon Henderson, worked with economist
Gardiner Means to report on the rigidity of high prices under
NRA’s policies, influencing Congress’s reluctance to renew NRA’s
charter. Rising meat prices led to consumers’ strikes against
butchers around the country. Consumers pledged not to buy until
the New Deal shifted its support from producers and processors
toward buyers. One of AAA’s consumer advocates, Donald
Montgomery, began campaigning against rising bread prices.
Having raised up the countervailing power of consumer
consciousness, the New Deal responded by shifting away from its
initial commitment to an alliance between government and
industry, and toward a more impartial role. 22
For these countervailing forces to have real effect they needed
independence. The South and West needed development so they
could generate their own wealth and capital, enabling them to
represent their own regional interests against the Northeast.
Workers and consumers needed organization and legitimacy so
they could represent their interests independently of business
management. In seeking to afford individual American workers
and consumers a greater degree of independence, the Roosevelt
administration determined to insure them against loss of income,
either temporarily, through cyclical unemployment, or
permanently, through disability or old age. To this end Roosevelt
appointed a Committee on Economic Security (CES) to draft plans
for social insurance.
97
C o u n te rv a ilin
g P o w e r
The report CES sent to Roosevelt called for universal coverage of the
American elderly by pensions paid for partly by their own
contributions and increasingly, over time, out of the general
revenues of the U.S. Treasury. Roosevelt rejected this plan, declaring
it was ‘‘the same old dole under another name’’—he wanted a self-
financing plan under which old-age pensions worked on the model
of insurance premiums. Workers and their employers would pay into
a fund a percentage of their paychecks. In the event of retirement in
old age, workers would draw a pension funded by their savings. The
7. Government posters such as this promoted Social Security. Other
posters promised support for widows and children of qualified
workers.
98
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
program would thus constitute ‘‘a wholly contributory scheme with
the government not participating,’’ as Roosevelt asked. 23
Critics immediately pointed out the drawbacks of this plan. No
other country financed social insurance this way, and for good
reason. Contributions calculated as a percent of payroll put a
relatively heavier tax burden on poorer earners. Within the
administration, Harry Hopkins pointed out the regressivity of the
payroll taxes and recommended a tax on wealthier Americans’
incomes instead. In the press, opinion-makers fretted that ‘‘the law
is almost a model of what legislation ought not to be,’’ as the New
Republic wrote. 24
The administration’s concern with fiscal soundness also prevented
the Social Security system from reaching all Americans. Because
the United States came late to the business of old-age insurance, it
had the advantage of other countries’ experience to examine. As
Abraham Epstein, an advocate of old-age insurance, noted in 1922,
‘‘It is evident that it can only be made to apply to persons who are
in regular employment. It is next to impossible to collect
contributions from persons who are irregularly employed, from
agricultural laborers, from those who are not their own employers,
from women who work at home not for wages, from small
merchants, and so forth.’’ 25
The Roosevelt administration
therefore sought to follow other countries that had excluded farm
workers and domestic servants from their old-age pension policies
at the start, and Congress complied.
The limits on Social Security would not last, nor did
administration officials think they would. Privately, the experts
knew that the contributory scheme would soon need
supplementing from the general treasury. Publicly, they avowed
their intention to expand the program to cover more workers
when they could. As amended in 1939 and 1950, the system
fulfilled these expectations. But for the moment of its creation,
Social Security stuck to the limits Roosevelt set on it.
99
C o u n te rv a ilin
g P o w e r
If the decisions to limit Social Security derived from a concern for
fiscal soundness, they had further effects peculiar to the American
workforce. The exclusion of farm workers and domestic servants
disproportionately affected African Americans. At a stroke,
Congress cut half the black workers in the country, and around 60
percent of those in the South, out of the Social Security system. If
this racial discrimination followed from innocent concerns for
fiscal stability, a further provision in the law could not so easily
escape criticism.
Social Security also included a program of direct assistance to
the elderly already beyond working age, who could not now
contribute to funding their own pensions, setting aside federal
funds to match whatever states spent to provide cash relief. It
included similar plans for aid to the blind or to needy dependent
children (chiefly the children of widowed mothers), on the
principle that they, like the elderly, constituted a class of deserving
unemployed people. The question of how much they deserved
remained open. 26
When determining how to allocate federal matching funds to the
states for assistance to the elderly poor (a program distinct from
the contributory insurance scheme), the Social Security proposal
initially imposed on the states a uniform standard of ‘‘decency and
health.’’ Representatives of southern states protested that to meet
this standard as acknowledged elsewhere in the country would
require them to quadruple their aid to the poor as, indeed, the
average income in the South amounted to as little as one quarter
of what Americans in richer states earned. This discrepancy
derived largely, as one southern senator admitted, from the
different labor market imposed on the ‘‘great many colored people’’
in the South. Despite the obvious racist tinge to southern
protestation, their provision passed with the administration’s
approval (and that of the sole African American in Congress,
Arthur Mitchell, Democrat of Illinois, who argued it was
unrealistic to expect a fourfold increase in a state’s relief bill). 27
100
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Social Security’s unemployment provisions resembled other parts
of the plan: as with old-age insurance, the federal component of
unemployment insurance would come from payroll taxes; as with
aid to the deserving and unemployable, states would be able to
determine the generosity of unemployment benefits. But
unemployment compensation went further to prevent too much
power from lodging in Washington. Once states established their
own unemployment compensation schemes, employers could
deduct what they paid their state governments from what they
owed the federal government. The law thus encouraged states to
establish unemployment insurance programs, rather than creating
a national plan.
If, as many later commenters would claim, Social Security became
the basis for the American welfare state, it did so despite its framers’
apparent intentions. Its principal provisions do not qualify as
welfare at all, nor as relief, owing to Roosevelt’s insistence that they
draw on beneficiaries’ contributions rather than the general
revenue. Americans did not enjoy these benefits as a matter of right,
only by virtue of their having bought into the plans, as they might
have with a private insurance program. Roosevelt wanted to limit
federal contributions to the barest minimum in the interest of fiscal
soundness—hence the contributory plan, hence the state
unemployment plans, hence the matching basis for old-age
assistance. ‘‘Not one nickel more. . . . Not one solitary nickel. Once
you get off the . . . matching basis the sky’s the limit, and before you
know it, we’ll be paying the whole bill.’’ 28
Nor did Social Security push the United States onto a course like
that followed by other modern nations, as American lawmakers
chose instead a contributory system of regressive taxation.
Adopting a progressive income tax for national benefits would not
only have mimicked other countries’ social spending and arguably
have served social justice, but it might also have done a better
job of fighting the Depression. But the New Dealers did not shape
Social Security as a Depression-fighting policy. Rather, it
101
C o u n te rv a ilin
g P o w e r
constituted a guarantee of Americans’ future independence from
their employers and thus as an underpinning of the strategy for
fostering countervailing power around the country. Moreover, it
represented a modest step in that direction: reformers on the
Committee on Economic Security believed that to make employees
properly independent, the United States needed a system of
national health insurance—but so vigorously did opponents,
particularly the American Medical Association, resist even efforts
to research the subject that the committee dropped it. 29
Rather
than increase the power of the state, New Dealers preferred to
increase the power of individual citizens and groups of citizens,
and did so within what they regarded as realistic political limits.
As Franklin Roosevelt headed to reelection in 1936, he could claim
to have worked both for the recovery of the American economy
and for its reform, in both the interest of a fairer marketplace
and the interest of the Democratic Party, which happened, owing
to geographic and historical peculiarities of the American
experience, to overlap. The South and the West needed economic
development; the industrial Northeast needed relief from the
severity of unemployment. All the great dams and roads and
bridges the Roosevelt administration built, the infrastructure that
brought the promise of modernity to the South and West,
amounted to a minority of the New Deal’s total spending, 60
percent of which went instead to relief that funneled chiefly to the
more urban states of the Northeast. 30
In responding to these needs Roosevelt was responding also to the
constituents he most needed: the consumers and the workers of
the industrial state and the voting citizens of the South and West,
all of whom drew strength and independence from his policies. As
they grew in power, they pushed the president to do more for them.
In the New Deal’s success lay the possibility of its demise: the
louder these voices grew, the more clearly they clamored for
differing goals. Roosevelt could keep them together only by
extraordinary efforts and the accidents of history.
102
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Notes
1. John Kenneth Galbraith, American Capitalism: The Concept
of Countervailing Power (New York: Transaction Publishers,
2004), 137.
2. Jason Scott Smith, Building New Deal Liberalism: The Political
Economy of Public Works, 1933–1956 (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2006), 120–21.
3. Thomas K. McCraw, TVA and the Power Fight, 1933–1939
(Philadelphia: J. B. Lippincott Company, 1971), 30.
4. Ibid., 1.
5. Ibid., 33.
6. 48 Stat. 58.
7. David Lilienthal, The TVA: An Experiment in The ‘‘Grass Roots’’
Administration of Federal Functions (Knoxville, TN: 1939).
8. McCraw, TVA, 138.
9. Theodore Saloutos, The American Farmer and the New Deal
(Ames: Iowa State University Press, 1982), 219.
10. McCraw, TVA, 142.
11. John Joseph Wallis, ‘‘The Political Economy of New Deal Spending
Revisited, Again: With and Without Nevada,’’ Explorations in
Economic History 35, no. 2 (1998).
12. Mark H. Leff, The Limits of Symbolic Reform: The New Deal and
Taxation, 1933–1939 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1984), 137, 56.
13. Meg Jacobs, Pocketbook Politics: Economic Citizenship in
Twentieth Century America (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 2005), 139.
14. Ibid., 137.
15. Ibid., 145.
16. 49 Stat. 449.
17. Irving L. Bernstein, Turbulent Years: A History of the American
Worker (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1971), 769–70.
18. ‘‘President’s Statement on Recovery Act Policies,’’ New York Times,
6/17/1933, 2.
19. ‘‘A Champion of the Consumer Speaks Out,’’ New York Times,
8/6/1933, SM5.
20. ‘‘Consumer Bureau to Check Prices,’’ New York Times, 6/24/1933,
22.
21. Jacobs, Pocketbook Politics, 119.
22. Ibid., 131–32.
103
C o u n te rv a ilin
g P o w e r
23. Mark H. Leff, ‘‘Taxing the ‘Forgotten Man’: The Politics of Social
Security and the New Deal,’’ Journal of American History 70, no. 2
(1983): 366–68.
24. Ibid.: 373.
25. Gareth Davies and Martha Derthick, ‘‘Race and Social Welfare
Policy: The Social Security Act of 1935,’’ Political Science Quarterly
112, no. 2 (1997): 222.
26. James T. Patterson, America’s Struggle against Poverty, 1900–
1985 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1986), 67–75.
27. Davies and Derthick, ‘‘Race and Social Welfare Policy,’’ 227.
28. James T. Patterson, The New Deal and the States: Federalism in
Transition (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1969), 93.
29. Daniel S. Hirshfield, The Lost Reform: The Campaign for
Compulsory Health Insurance in the United States from 1932 to
1943 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1970), 42–70.
30. Wallis, ‘‘Political Economy,’’ 167.
104
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Chapter 7
The End of the Beginning
Franklin Delano Roosevelt spoke with an apparently easy
confidence and in the accent of an upper class indigenous to
the country but normally concealed from most Americans
behind the stone walls and tree-lined roads of the Hudson River
Valley and Long Island. His ancestors had come to New
Amsterdam in the seventeenth century, and his family never
strayed far, though governments fell and rose, some abetted by
Roosevelts. His mother’s family, the Delanos, were merchants.
He attended Groton and Harvard, schools chiefly for rich, white,
Protestant boys. When he married his distant cousin Eleanor
Roosevelt (making her Eleanor Roosevelt Roosevelt) he acquired
as uncle-by-marriage President Theodore Roosevelt, in whose
footsteps he followed as a state legislator, assistant secretary of
the navy, and governor of New York. Were it not for his bout
with adult polio, which left him unable to stand without much
pain, effort, and assistance, he would have endured no evident
hardship and, indeed, all the privilege a democratic country
could offer.
Nothing in his background made him look anything like a tribune
of the people; neither did he run as one in 1932, when he criticized
Hoover for running deficits, nor preside as one afterward. In
the United States as throughout the industrial world, the
circumstances favored the growth of social spending policies, yet
105
Roosevelt himself, as leader of the party more favorable to such
programs, resisted them. Sometimes his fiscal conservatism availed
nothing, as when he opposed deposit insurance or exhibited
indifference to the National Labor Relations Act until it had all but
passed Congress anyway. Sometimes his conservatism
permanently shaped American social policy, as when he
determined the contributory and federal structure of the Social
Security system. And despite his willingness to experiment, these
fiscally conservative impulses never left him, which made the
Roosevelt who emerged in 1936 as the champion of labor and the
loudest philosopher of countervailing power all the more peculiar.
When nominated for president by his party that summer, he
declared war on ‘‘the privileged princes of these new economic
dynasties. . . . These economic royalists complain that we seek to
overthrow the institutions of America. What they really complain
of is that we seek to take away their power. Our allegiance to
American institutions requires the overthrow of this kind of
power.’’ 1 Roosevelt went on to ‘‘heartily subscribe’’ to ‘‘the brave
and clear platform of this Convention,’’ which listed ‘‘malefactors of
great wealth’’ near ‘‘kidnappers and bandits’’ in the lineup of the
nation’s enemies. 2
Roosevelt’s opponents would sometimes call him a traitor to his
class, but as the historian Richard Hofstadter observed in 1948, ‘‘if
by his class one means the whole policy-making, power-wielding
stratum, it would be just as true to say that his class betrayed him.’’ 3
Despite Roosevelt’s care in constructing the New Deal, despite the
restraint and caution and respect for American federalism of the
New Deal’s every measure, despite the overriding evidence in both
word and deed that the Roosevelt administration came time
after time to rescue American capitalism and had no intention of
replacing it, Roosevelt met at best foot-dragging, often
disingenuous cooperation; as the New Deal succeeded and the
Depression lessened, outright hostility from members of his class
who (it turned out ) regarded even slight shifts in the social order
as portents of anarchy.
106
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
As much as the Democratic Party depended on the votes of
segregationist whites, and as much as the Roosevelt administration
built New Deal programs to respect the institutions of federalism
and states’ rights precisely to avoid disturbing the racial politics of
the South, the New Deal nevertheless did more to assist African
Americans than the Hoover administration had and more than the
old Democratic Party had. The ideal of assisting the ‘‘forgotten
man’’ compelled New Dealers with a sense of shame and history to
remember that black Americans more routinely fell into that
category than any other class. As First Lady, Eleanor Roosevelt
ranked high among such New Dealers. She had in youth worked in
a settlement house that helped the immigrant poor of New York
City; she showed such sensitivity to the issues of class and race that
she became the channel through which civil rights leaders like
Walter White of the National Association for the Advancement of
Colored People (NAACP) could make themselves heard in the
8. Ben Shahn photographed this ‘‘White Trade Only’’ sign—one of
many around the country—in Lancaster, Ohio, for the Farm Security
Administration in 1938.
107
T h e E n d o f th e B e g in n in g
White House. In particular, she pushed Hopkins at WPA to ensure
that relief went to black, as well as white, workers. 4 Such efforts
produced only partial success—CCC, for example, noticeably
resisted racial integration—but the New Deal made inroads into
black joblessness as no program, federal or state, Democratic or
Republican, previously had. 5
These changes undermined southern whites’ sense of privilege, and
some took this threat so seriously they decided to seek redress.
One, a retired executive of the du Pont corporation, wrote another
du Pont executive early in 1934 to complain, ‘‘Five negroes on my
place in South Carolina refused work this spring . . . saying they had
easy jobs with the government,’’ and received the reply that
perhaps some organization should appear, ‘‘for educating the
people to the value of encouraging people to work; encouraging
people to get rich[.]’’ 6 From this spark emerged the American
Liberty League, which one Roosevelt aide derided as like
cellophane—‘‘first, it’s a du Pont product and second, you can see
right through it’’—which is to say its members, despite their
expressed nonpartisan concern for the U.S. Constitution, had
clearly no higher goal in mind than defeating Roosevelt in 1936. 7
A year later, the Liberty League got a valuable ally in its opposition
to the New Deal: the Supreme Court of the United States. On May
27, 1935, Chief Justice Charles Evans Hughes read the majority
opinion in the case of Schechter v. United States. The Schechter
slaughterhouse owners had been convicted in federal court for
selling an ‘‘unfit chicken’’ and other violations of the National
Recovery Administration (NRA) code for the poultry industry.
Hughes argued, contrary to the preamble of more than one New
Deal law, ‘‘Extraordinary conditions do not create or enlarge
constitutional power.’’ The Court believed that NRA represented
an unlawful delegation of power from Congress to the president
and thence to the code-making authorities, and particularly that it
too broadly interpreted Congress’s constitutional ability to regulate
interstate commerce. 8
108
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
On May 31, Roosevelt held a press conference—‘‘the first of its kind
in White House history where a president, speaking
informally . . . outlined without reference to a manuscript an
issue which appeared to him as second in importance only to war,’’
as a New York Times reporter wrote. 9 The president read from
telegrams pleading with him to restore NRA regulations, one of
which suggested stripping the Supreme Court of its jurisdiction
over the industrial codes. But, Roosevelt said, ‘‘these telegrams are
futile.’’ The Court’s decision in Schechter was, he said, ‘‘more
important than any decision probably since the Dred Scott case’’
(the case insisting the federal government had no power to
prohibit slavery in the U.S. territories, which precipitated the Civil
War) because the Court relied on a strict definition of the
Constitution’s commerce clause. Roosevelt read the decision as
preventing the federal government from regulating
manufacturing, mining, agriculture, and construction, even if
the raw materials or finished products of those activities crossed
state lines. And in a country dependent on interstate commerce, a
country transformed by modern transportation and
communication into a single nation, this reading of the law
rendered the federal government impotent. ‘‘We have forty-eight
Nations from now on. . . . It is a perfectly ridiculous and impossible
situation,’’ Roosevelt declared. The strict interpretation of the
commerce clause might have worked when little trade crossed state
lines and the nation’s people moved by ‘‘horse-and-buggy.’’ But
now that ‘‘We are interdependent—we are tied together,’’ Roosevelt
said, the United States needed a national government. ‘‘Now, as
to the way out . . . ’’ Roosevelt began, then stopped himself.
‘‘I suppose you will want to know something about what I am going
to do. I am going to tell you very, very little on that,’’ he said. 10
Nor did he, for more than a year, say anything substantial in public
about the Supreme Court and the New Deal, not even when the
Court invalidated the Agricultural Adjustment Administration the
following January and a set of other New Deal measures afterward.
His opponents spoke volumes. Liberty Leaguers began lionizing
109
T h e E n d o f th e B e g in n in g
the justices as defenders of the American Way. And Roosevelt’s
opponents began declaring that the issue of the upcoming election
would be the Court. Conservative Democrat Eugene Talmadge of
Georgia asked whether America’s voters wanted ‘‘a bunch of
Communists . . . to appoint the successors’’ to the aging justices.
Republicans said Roosevelt had gone beyond the conventions of
American civility with his ‘‘horse-and-buggy’’ comments, and
their nominee, Governor Alf Landon of Kansas, said that Roosevelt
had ‘‘cracked up.’’ 11 Senator Arthur Vandenberg (R-MI),
disingenuously ruminated, ‘‘I don’t think the President has any
thought of emulating Mussolini, Hitler or Stalin, but his utterance
as I have heard it is exactly what these men would say.’’ 12
Although Roosevelt said little, his administration and Congress
kept active, passing the Wagner Act to re-create and strengthen
labor’s right to organize as recognized in the National Industrial
Recovery Act, and passing the Guffey Coal Act to create a
miniature NRA specifically for the bituminous coal industry, on
the grounds that this industry operated on a truly interstate
scope. 13
The Court kept pace with the New Dealers, invalidating the Coal
Act in May 1936, as one of a string of decisions that over the course
of a year pitted its majorities against the New Deal in opinions that
struck Felix Frankfurter, then a law professor at Harvard, as
‘‘written for morons’’ and left him fuming, ‘‘Apparently history and
precedents mean nothing.’’ 14
Nor were Harvard faculty the only
Americans appalled. The president reliably received letters from
constituents complaining, as one Texas man did, that ‘‘I told you
the Rich Men always Run to the Supreme Court to Beat Our
Laws.’’ 15
Ultimately the Court outstripped the federal legislators and ran
ahead to put a roadblock in front of the states. In Morehead v.
New York ex. rel. Tipaldo, the Court ruled that states could not set
minimum wages for women workers. Roosevelt mildly
110
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
commented, ‘‘It seems to be fairly clear . . . that the ‘no-man’s-land’
where no Government—State or Federal—can function is being
more clearly defined. A State cannot do it and the Federal
Government cannot do it.’’ 16
Some Republicans recognized that
with this decision, defending the Supreme Court no longer looked
like such a fine election strategy. Congressman Hamilton Fish
(R-NY) said, ‘‘I say to my Republican friends if you lend or express
any sympathy for this decision . . . it will mean a million votes for
the Democratic party.’’ Herbert Hoover remarked, ‘‘something
should be done to give back to the states the powers they thought
they already had.’’ 17
But by now the Republicans had so thoroughly committed
themselves to a policy of standing with the Court against Roosevelt
they could not easily reverse course. At the Republican National
Convention, Hoover insisted, ‘‘The American should thank Almighty
God for the Constitution and the Supreme Court,’’ and got two
minutes’ applause. 18 In the New York Times, Arthur Krock wrote,
‘‘the court knows itself to be on trial.’’ 19 If so, the Court had put itself
in the dock, and the Republicans had climbed in with it—Roosevelt,
in his near-total silence on judicial issues, had little to do with it.
The election amounted to a referendum on the Court only inasmuch
as it ranked much more importantly as a referendum on the New
Deal, and not the New Deal as a particular program or even a success
but as a willingness to use the power of the U.S. government on
behalf of working and suffering Americans. While his opponents
stood by the Supreme Court and against the New Deal, Roosevelt
stood by the New Deal and against the Depression. In Madison
Square Garden on October 31, he said, ‘‘Tonight I call the roll—the
roll of honor of those who stood with us in 1932 and still stand with
us today. Written on it are the names of millions who never had a
chance—men at starvation wages, women in sweatshops, children at
looms.’’ And arrayed against them
the old enemies of peace—business and financial monopoly,
speculation, reckless banking, class antagonism, sectionalism, war
111
T h e E n d o f th e B e g in n in g
profiteering.Theyhad begun toconsidertheGovernmentoftheUnited
Statesasa mere appendage to their ownaffairs. . . . They are unanimous
in their hate for me—and I welcome their hatred. I should like to
have it said of my first Administration that in it the forces of selfishness
and of lust for power met their match. I should like to have it said
of my second Administration that in it these forces met their master.20
The electorate assented. All the states but Maine and Vermont
went for Roosevelt. No president had enjoyed such a majority in
the electoral college since James Monroe ran virtually unopposed
in 1820, and Roosevelt won a larger share of the popular vote
(more than 60 percent) than any other candidate since careful
record-keeping began in 1824. 21
Roosevelt won unprecedented
majorities of African American and Jewish voters. But most
importantly he drew working people to the polls in record numbers
to vote for the president they knew stood by them. Pollsters
found that middle-class people were more likely to vote for the
president than the rich, and the working class were more likely to
vote for the president than the middle class. Even within the
working class, this gradation showed itself: going down the scale of
skills, the less-skilled workers were more likely to support the
president than the more-skilled ones. The American people had a
good idea where their president stood. As one wrote him, ‘‘you are
the one & only President that ever helped a Working Class of
People.’’ 22
At the same time, the voices in the land that had sought
to challenge Roosevelt for leadership of the middle and working
classes had fallen silent. Huey Long had been murdered the year
before. Father Charles Coughlin, the radio priest, led an
unsuccessful third party effort, earned rebuke from the Catholic
Church for his politics, and lost listeners as he became increasingly
anti-Semitic. Even the Communist Party in the United States
avoided criticizing Roosevelt. 23
The astounding national majority that Roosevelt had built would
last for about thirty years, but even at the moment of its triumph
the fissures that would crack it apart had already opened. A
112
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
coalition whose political program as a matter of principle used the
federal government to aid working-class, ethnic, and African
Americans was a coalition that appealed almost entirely to urban
Americans. This coalition might well succeed in electing a
president, as populous cities could carry populous states with many
electoral votes. But the structure of Congress and especially of the
Senate resisted this politics of class and city, largely because the
eighteenth-century framers meant the Congress to do just that.
Rural areas, areas with smaller towns, and the white South with its
persistent racist politics looked with increasing hostility on the
Roosevelt administration as the president—with increasing
frankness—declared himself the champion of the country’s
downtrodden. Roosevelt won reelection on a newly clear New
Deal, but he also laid bare the difference between the New Deal
and the Democratic Party. 24
Roosevelt spent the first year of his second term clarifying this
difference in a manner he would not have chosen, with his first major
political loss. Despite the president’s own silence about the Supreme
Court in 1936, advocates of judicial reform spoke often about
changing the Court’s composition, recalling the Reconstruction era
when a Republican Congress had stripped the Court of jurisdiction
in some cases and shifted its numbers. One of the president’s
advisors discovered that the New Deal’s great foe on the Court,
Justice James McReynolds, when serving as Woodrow Wilson’s
attorney general in 1913, had proposed to reform the federal
judiciary by requiring the appointment of a new judge for each
judge who did not retire on his seventieth birthday. The Supreme
Court’s four most anti-New Deal justices were all over seventy, and
none of the justices was under sixty. Roosevelt settled on
McReynolds’s plan for increasing the Court’s numbers—or as
supporters privately and opponents publicly said, ‘‘packing’’ the
Court. 25
Well before the president committed himself to the plan, the Court
apparently reacted. In December, after the election but before the
113
T h e E n d o f th e B e g in n in g
inauguration, Justice Owen Roberts, who had previously voted
with four other anti-New Deal justices to make a majority on the
Court, switched his vote to a new, pro-New Deal majority in a case
that looked to almost all observers like a frank reversal. The Court
would not read its opinion in West Coast Hotel v. Parrish until
March, but in it the justices said the opposite of what they had said
in Tipaldo—that the states could indeed legislate minimum
wages. 26
And soon they would uphold the Wagner Act and the
Social Security Act, and afterward seemed much friendlier to the
New Deal in all its respects.
Yet Roosevelt went ahead with his plan to shift the Court.
Supporters could claim the idea had obvious merits: the
Republicans packed the Court during Reconstruction; Theodore
Roosevelt advocated similar measures during and after his
presidency; when Franklin Roosevelt entered office fewer than 30
percent of federal judges were Democrats and through his entire
first term he had not been able to appoint a Supreme Court
justice; Tipaldo in particular struck almost everyone as obviously
at odds with the times and tradition. 27
But the Court-packing plan
presented an excellent opportunity to level at Roosevelt the charge
of dictatorial ambition which, in an unsettled age of actual
dictators in developed countries, carried special weight. The
Senate Judiciary Committee issued a report repudiating the
president’s plan as a ‘‘needless, futile, and utterly dangerous
abandonment of constitutional principle’’ that reminded them of
the misfortunes other countries’ political systems had recently
suffered. Seven of the ten signers were Democrats. As one
journalist wrote, the report looked like conservative Democrats’
‘‘document of secession.’’ 28
As the summer went on, and the Court looked ever more
conciliatory, Roosevelt’s Court-packing plan looked increasingly
unnecessary. It finally went down to defeat amid death—Senator
Joseph T. Robinson (D-AR), Roosevelt’s floor leader, died while
pressing the bill—and death threats from vigilante opponents of
114
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
the president, and the administration’s congressional support
faded away. 29
The protracted Court fight and the split within the Democratic
Party worked with a larger hardship to undermine the New Deal.
For the first time since Roosevelt’s election and with sickening
speed, the country plunged into economic recession, imperiling the
New Deal’s claims to success. It did not look like an ordinary
reversal of the business cycle, as the economy had clearly not
completely recovered from the fall of 1929. Administration critics
blamed the recession on Roosevelt. They said he had scared
businessmen into holding onto their capital, thus preventing them
from making productive investments, and they also blamed the
Social Security taxes, which had gone into effect in 1937, for
removing money from the economy. Within the administration,
New Dealers blamed businessmen for deliberately refusing to
invest—for starting what they called a ‘‘capital strike,’’ to discredit
the New Deal—and they too blamed Roosevelt: in a resurgence of
his fiscal conservatism, Roosevelt had ordered cuts in public works
spending with the goal of balancing the budget. 30
As New Deal
spending fell, unemployment rose. 31
In a private letter to the president dated February 1, 1938, John
Maynard Keynes argued that Roosevelt ought to act as if all critics
were right. Cutting relief spending was, Keynes said, ‘‘an error of
optimism,’’ and renewed spending on public works would help
reverse the downturn. At the same time, Keynes noted, the United
States needed private enterprise to help solve its problems: ‘‘You
could do anything you liked with them, if you would treat them
(even the big ones), not as wolves and tigers, but as domestic
animals by nature, even though they have been badly brought up
and not trained as you would wish. . . . If you work them into the
surly, obstinate, terrified mood, of which domestic animals,
wrongly handled, are so capable, the nation’s burdens will not get
carried to market.’’ So Roosevelt needed to reenlist businessmen in
the recovery effort. Keynes’s recommendations carried extra
115
T h e E n d o f th e B e g in n in g
weight now, as he had in 1936 published The General Theory of
Employment, Money, and Interest, which together with the
recession encouraged American economists to believe that a
government’s deficit spending could bring about a recovery from
recession by getting consumers to buy more. 32
Roosevelt acted as if he believed at least half of Keynes’s argument.
In the spring of 1938, Roosevelt asked for a resumption of public
works spending, admitting that it ‘‘began to taper off too quickly’’
in 1937. 33
In June, Congress obliged, making about $3 billion
available for renewed relief spending and dramatically raising
federal contributions to the economy. 34
But by this time the Court
fight and the recession had weakened Roosevelt. Apart from the
increase of relief spending, he got from Congress the Fair Labor
Standards Act, which banned child labor and set a federal
minimum wage. 35
But Roosevelt won that law only with
considerable help from a long campaign waged by the National
Consumers’ League and some major labor unions. 36
Afterward the
New Dealers could no longer produce significant new law.
The president now attacked two major sources of opposition.
Against organized business, Roosevelt arrayed the Temporary
National Economic Committee (TNEC), which aimed to expose
the bad practices of monopolists. And against conservative
southern Democrats he launched a personal campaign. Both
efforts failed. TNEC conducted hearings into various industries
and considered a variety of methods to end, or at least to regulate,
monopolies. While it discovered and duly reported reams of data
on American industry, it came up with no clear proposal for action
against the trusts and holding companies that controlled American
businesses. But it did emphasize that government must play the
role Keynes prescribed, of promoting prosperity by spending
gauged to encourage consumer purchasing. 37
Roosevelt himself took a more traditionally partisan approach to
the economy, identifying the South as ‘‘the Nation’s No. 1 economic
116
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
problem,’’ and targeting it as the Democratic Party’s number one
political problem: ‘‘I think the South is going to remain
Democratic, but I think it is going to be a more intelligent form of
democracy than has kept the South for other reasons, in the
Democratic column for all these years. . . . it is going to be a liberal
democracy.’’ 38
Roosevelt campaigned without success against
sitting southern Democrats through the summer of 1938, and they
reacted by invoking the specter that had stirred white southern
hearts since the Civil War: outside interference by Yankee
agitators. In the November congressional elections, the American
electorate registered general disillusionment with the president,
returning a House of Representatives in which the Democratic
delegation lost seventy-two seats and a Senate in which the
Democratic delegation lost seven seats. 39
Roosevelt’s prediction
proved incorrect. The South would not turn liberal, nor even
remain Democratic if the Democrats insisted on trying to change
its race relations: in ten years’ time, his successor, Harry S Truman,
would narrowly avoid defeat when the South bolted the
Democratic Party because it adopted the cause of civil rights for
African Americans.
From the high of 1936 to the low of 1938, Roosevelt demonstrated
what the New Deal could and could not do to American politics.
On a national level at the polls in a presidential election, the
president could successfully present himself as the champion of the
people and their New Deal against an old guard of the rich and
hidebound. He could ride the rhetoric and the reality of class
politics to reelection. But American laws and customs do not
provide for the national organization of politics. And against a
Congress elected from localities, against a Senate elected from
states, Roosevelt’s cross-sectional politics foundered. In 1938 the
president’s mailbag clearly showed the divisions between sections
of the country. While some wrote with praise and to ask, as one
woman did, ‘‘How can anybody be against you?! You have kept so
many parents and children together through W.P.A.,’’ others
clearly were against him. One woman said, ‘‘It makes me sick at
117
T h e E n d o f th e B e g in n in g
heart, to think you have nothing on your program only the same
old thing you have had for 5 yrs. just giving to those who will take
it,’’ and one man asked, ‘‘Did it ever enter your head that the
country ran before your time and will after your gone?’’ 40
It is also fair to say that apart from health insurance, Roosevelt and
Congress between them set in place American versions of the
major components of social security as it existed in other industrial
countries, including provision for the elderly, the unemployed,
the disabled, and the otherwise dependent. They shored up the
banks and the currency and, by their lights, saved American
capitalism. They launched the development of underdeveloped
regions in the South and the West. True, some goals failed, like the
extension of the TVA model to other regions. 41
And already the
Democrats had discovered the political peril that awaited them
when they edged even a little bit toward the specifically American
necessity of civil rights for black citizens.
Late in the 1930s, policymakers who had come to Washington to
change the way the nation worked found themselves increasingly
asked to find ways to make the existing structure of the American
economy work a bit better. Agencies like the National Resources
Planning Board discounted the idea of structural changes in favor
of using government to improve existing institutions. 42
Congress
patched up programs, re-creating AAA to keep parity policies in
place without offending the Supreme Court and amending Social
Security. New Dealers increasingly accepted the policy generally
described as Keynesianism—that through the federal budget they
could promote Americans’ spending and thus overall economic
growth without meddling in the basic workings or balance of the
economy.
But though at the legislative level the creative phase of the New
Deal was ending, as an idea distilled from those legislative conflicts
and compromises it had only just begun its life. The idea was a
simple one, as a WPA relief worker said in 1938:
118
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
The way I look at it is this. This is a rich country. I figger it ain’t going
to hurt the government to feed and clothe them that needs it. Half of
’em can’t get work, or just ain’t fixed to handle work if they get
it. . . . We’ve got the money. Plenty of it. No sense in the big fellows
kicking about a little handout to the poor. Matter’s not if some ain’t
deserving. . . . Lot of ’em that comes here, why I’d sooner give them a
kick in the pants than shove ’em out supplies. But you got to take the
good with the bad. Or bad with the good, whichever way you’ve a
mind to put it. 43
The idea in this speech, the idea that it did a rich country no harm
to help even the unworthy poor came out of the New Deal; and so
indeed did the speech itself and so also did the idea that a rich
country ought to record and keep it, plain utterance of an ordinary
person though it was.
The speech remains because WPA preserved it, along with the
musings of many other Americans. The Federal Writers’ Project
of WPA, together with a number of other similar projects, sent
writers around the country to record Americans—not just their
opinions of the New Deal, or the Depression, or the president, but
anything and everything, their lives and hopes and ambitions and
idle irritations, not to ennoble the New Deal or the nation but
simply to give the culture a record of itself and its people. The
writers worked as carefully as they could, following instructions to
‘‘take down the exact words of the informant.’’ 44
They recorded
how Americans spoke, sang, worked, and played. Their colleagues
with cameras recorded how the people and the country looked.
They interviewed current sharecroppers and former slaves: ‘‘I lays
in the bunk two days, getting over that whipping, gitting over it in
the body but not the heart. No sir, I has that in the heart to this
day.’’ 45
They found onetime pioneer settlers, and Indians who
remembered when the pioneer settlers came. They wrote down
tall tales, ghost stories, and folk songs, the stuff of the country’s
rural past now vanishing in the newly national, urban nation. And
they published it, in The Jewish Landsmanschaften of New York
119
T h e E n d o f th e B e g in n in g
(1938), U.S. One: Maine to Florida (1938), The Negro in Virginia
(1940), The Havasupai and the Hualapai (1940), among dozens of
other books on every state and people and feature of the landscape.
With the Federal Art Project and the Federal Theatre Project,
WPA also made new culture for the country. The art project made
murals and posters with a distinctive visual style. And the theater
project ensured that Americans could see plays like Macbeth or
Dr. Faustus, The Mikado or an adaptation of Sinclair Lewis’s novel
warning about the potential for fascism in America, It Can’t
Happen Here, not only in New York but in cities around the
country.
These cultural ambitions of the New Deal came to grief on the
same opposition as its political ambitions. Conservative,
particularly southern, Democrats like Congressman Martin Dies
of Texas, began fretting publicly about Communist influence on
the New Deal. Dies’s Un-American Activities Committee began
hearings in 1938 to investigate the influence of Communism
on unions and the New Deal broadly, including the Federal
Theatre Project. In December, Hallie Flanagan, the Project’s
director, went before the committee. When she mentioned
Christopher Marlowe, who wrote Dr. Faustus, Congressman
Joseph Starnes asked her, ‘‘You are quoting from this Marlowe.
Is he a Communist?’’ Flanagan replied, ‘‘Put in the
record . . . that he was the greatest dramatist in the period
of Shakespeare, immediately preceding Shakespeare.’’ 46
The
exchange illustrated the breadth of the gap between the culture
the New Dealers were promulgating and the culture in some
regions of the country asked to appreciate it. By 1939 the
Dies Committee had helped end funding for the Federal
Theatre Project, and the conservatives in Congress turned their
attention to other New Deal agencies. In the summer of 1939
they began looking into NLRB, and conservative Democrats
and Republicans voted together to defeat spending bills
Roosevelt had proposed. 47
120
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
As conservative opposition stymied him, Roosevelt began thinking
past the New Deal. One of his advisors said that in 1940 the
president told him, ‘‘he has probably gone as far as he can on
domestic questions.’’ The war in Europe began to claim his
attention. And though he would tell the remaining New Dealers
‘‘we must start winning the war,’’ he did not quite abandon the New
Deal, even as the nation began to fight. 48
9. Poster for the Federal Theatre Project staging of Sinclair Lewis’s It
Can’t Happen Here.
121
T h e E n d o f th e B e g in n in g
Notes
1. Franklin D. Roosevelt, ‘‘Acceptance Speech for the Renomination
for the Presidency,’’ June 27, 1936, Philadelphia, PA. Checked
online, 2/27/2007, at www.presidency.ucsb.edu/
shownomination.php?convid¼37. 2. James MacGregor Burns, Roosevelt: The Lion and the Fox (New
York: Harcourt, Brace and Company, 1956), 272.
3. Richard Hofstadter, The American Political Tradition and the Men
Who Made It (New York: Vintage, 1989), 435.
4. Harvard Sitkoff, A New Deal for Blacks (New York: Oxford
University Press, 1978), 60.
5. Bruce J. Schulman, From Cotton Belt to Sunbelt: Federal Policy,
Economic Development, and the Transformation of the South,
1938–1980 (Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 1994), 34.
6. Frederick Rudolph, ‘‘The American Liberty League, 1934–1940,’’
The American Historical Review 56, no. 1 (1950): 19.
7. William E. Leuchtenburg, The FDR Years: On Roosevelt and His
Legacy (New York: Columbia University Press, 1995), 124.
10. This WPA Federal Art Project mural in San Francisco’s George
Washington High School depicts a scene from the American
Revolution.
122
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
8. 295 U.S. 495, 528.
9. Charles W. Hurd, ‘‘President Says End of NRA Puts Control Up to
People,’’ New York Times 6/1/1935, 1.
10. Franklin D. Roosevelt, press conference, May 31, 1935. Checked
online, 3/1/2007, www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/
print.php?pid¼15065. 11. William E. Leuchtenburg, ‘‘When the People Spoke, What Did They
Say?: The Election of 1936 and the Ackerman Thesis,’’ Yale Law
Journal 108, no. 8 (1999): 2088, 2080.
12. Leuchtenburg, ‘‘The Origins of Franklin D. Roosevelt’s ‘Court-
Packing’ Plan,’’ Supreme Court Review 1966 (1966): 358.
13. 49 Stat. 991; ‘‘The Bituminous Coal Conservation Act of 1935,’’ Yale
Law Journal 45, no. 2 (1935).
14. Leuchtenburg, ‘‘When the People Spoke,’’ 2106; Leuchtenburg,
‘‘Comment on Laura Kalman’s Article, ‘The Constitution, the
Supreme Court, and the New Deal’,’’ American Historical Review
110, no. 4 (2005).
15. Leuchtenburg, ‘‘The Origins of Franklin D. Roosevelt’s
‘Court-Packing’ Plan,’’ 355.
16. Leuchtenberg, ‘‘When the People Spoke,’’ 2084.
17. Ibid., 2090.
18. Ibid.
19. Arthur Krock, ‘‘In Washington,’’ New York Times 5/27/1936, 22.
20. Franklin D. Roosevelt, ‘‘Address at Madison Square Garden, New
York City,’’ 10/31/1936. Checked online 3/7/2007 at
www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/print.php?pid¼15219. 21. Leuchtenburg, FDR Years, 145–46.
22. Ibid., 153.
23. Alan Brinkley, The End of Reform: New Deal Liberalism in
Recession and War (New York: Vintage, 1995), 257–62,
Leuchtenburg, FDR Years, 137.
24. James T. Patterson, Congressional Conservatism and the New
Deal: The Growth of the Conservative Coalition in Congress, 1933–
1939 (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1981).
25. Leuchtenburg, ‘‘The Origins of Franklin D. Roosevelt’s ‘Court-
Packing’ Plan,’’ 390–99.
26. Leuchtenburg , ‘‘Comment on Laura Kalman’s Article.’’
27. Leuchtenburg, ‘‘The Origins of Franklin D. Roosevelt’s ‘Court-
Packing’ Plan,’’ 349, n. 8.
28. Leuchtenburg, ‘‘FDR’s Court-Packing Plan: A Second Life, a
Second Death,’’ Duke Law Journal 1985, no. 3/4 (1985): 675–77.
123
T h e E n d o f th e B e g in n in g
29. Ibid.: 685–87.
30. ‘‘PresidentPlans600,000WPACut,’’NewYorkTimes,1/26/1937,2.
31. Patrick Renshaw, ‘‘Was There a Keynesian Economy in the USA
between 1933 and 1945?,’’ Journal of Contemporary History 34,
no. 3 (1999): 343–44.
32. William J. Barber, Designs within Disorder: Franklin D. Roosevelt,
the Economists, and the Shaping of American Economic Policy,
1933–1945 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996),
108–12; Brinkley, End of Reform, 82–85, 94–97.
33. Lester V. Chandler, American Monetary Policy, 1928–41 (New
York: Harper and Row, 1971), 325–26.
34. 52 Stat. 809 and E. Cary Brown, ‘‘Fiscal Policy in the ’Thirties:
A Reappraisal,’’ American Economic Review 46, no. 5 (1956);
Chandler, American Monetary Policy, 254.
35. 52 Stat. 1060.
36. Landon R. Y. Storrs, Civilizing Capitalism: The National
Consumers’ League, Women’s Activism, and Labor Standards in
the New Deal Era (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press,
2000), 177–205.
37. Brinkley, End of Reform, 122–31.
38. Schulman, From Cotton Belt, 49–50.
39. Checked on the Clerk of the House website, 3/8/2007, http://
clerk.house.gov/art_history/house_history/partyDiv.html, and the
Senate Historian website, 3/8/2007, www.senate.gov/pagelayout/
history/one_item_and_teasers/partydiv.htm.
40. Lawrence W. Levine and Cornelia R. Levine, eds., The People and
the President: America’s Conversation with FDR (Boston: Beacon
Press, 2002), 234–35, 241.
41. Leuchtenburg, ‘‘Roosevelt, Norris and the ‘Seven Little TVAs,’ ’’
Journal of Politics 14, no. 3 (1952).
42. Patrick D. Reagan, Designing a New America: The Origins of New
Deal Planning, 1890–1943 (Amherst: University of Massachusetts
Press, 1999); Brinkley, End of Reform, 245–61.
43. [Federal Writers’ Project], These Are Our Lives (New York: W. W.
Norton, 1975), 366.
44. Joint Committee on Folk Arts, WPA folksong questionnaire,
1939. Library of Congress Digital ID AFCTS wpa001, viewed
online 3/8/07.
45. Jerre Mangione, The Dream and the Deal: The Federal Writers’
Project, 1935–1943 (New York: Avon, 1972), 264.
124
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
46. Roy Rosenzweig and Barbara Melosh, ‘‘Government and the Arts:
Voices from the New Deal Era,’’ Journal of American History 77,
no. 2 (1990): 596.
47. Patterson, Congressional Conservatism, 321–22.
48. Brinkley, End of Reform, 144.
125
T h e E n d o f th e B e g in n in g
Conclusion
The New American Way at
Home and Around the World
In November 1938, just months after the Fair Labor Standards Act
passed, Roosevelt privately told his secretary of the treasury, Henry
Morgenthau, that the world’s slide into war might well benefit
Americans generally and the Democrats politically. ‘‘These foreign
orders’’ for armaments, Roosevelt said, ‘‘mean prosperity in this
country and we can’t elect a Democratic Party unless we get
prosperity.’’ At the same time Roosevelt began thinking about
building up American military power as a deterrent, to avoid
having to negotiate with Hitler. 1 Despite losses in the 1938
congressional elections, the Democratic Party remained in power,
as did Roosevelt for an unprecedented third term in 1940. And in a
few years he told reporters he ‘‘no longer like[d] the term ‘New
Deal’,’’ that ‘‘Dr. New Deal’’ had come to save the country from
one set of ills, but now that it faced new perils, ‘‘his
partner . . . Dr. Win-the-War,’’ would take over. 2
Roosevelt’s substitution of ‘‘win-the-war’’ for ‘‘New Deal’’ mirrored
shifts in the federal budget. Congress ended the New Deal, even as
war allowed the government to spend the public’s money with a
zeal and abandon that mere global economic crisis could not
support. By the end of 1943, Congress had abolished CCC, WPA,
and other New Deal agencies. 3 At the same time, federal spending
grew from 8 percent of US GDP in 1938 to 40 percent in 1943. 4
The war let federal officials hire Americans directly without a
126
second thought as to whether they were instituting anything so un-
American as national work-relief. War spending and employment
dwarfed Depression spending and employment, and in 1943, at
long last, unemployment (measured as a percentage of the civilian
labor force) dropped below its 1929 level. 5 As the economist E. Cary
Brown noted in 1956, the New Deal never seriously tested Keynes’s
recommendations: ‘‘[f]iscal policy, then, seems to have been an
unsuccessful recovery device in the ’thirties—not because it did not
work, but because it was not tried.’’ 6 Only the war brought that
trial, and then not as an experiment in recovery, but as an incident
of military necessity.
Yet the war did not wholly displace the idea of the New Deal,
and when Roosevelt began to consider what lay beyond the
fighting, he resorted to the ideals of the 1930s. In January 1944,
Roosevelt delivered his State of the Union address, declaring, ‘‘It is
our duty now to begin to lay the plans and determine the strategy
for the winning of a lasting peace. . . . We have come to a clear
realization of the fact that true individual freedom cannot exist
without economic security and independence.’’ He then went on to
list, ‘‘a second Bill of Rights under which a new basis of security
and prosperity can be established for all regardless of station, race,
or creed.’’ The new rights included
The right to a useful and remunerative job in the industries or
shops or farms or mines of the Nation;
The right to earn enough to provide adequate food and clothing
and recreation;
The right of every farmer to raise and sell his products at a return
which will give him and his family a decent living;
The right of every businessman, large and small, to trade in an
atmosphere of freedom from unfair competition and domination
by monopolies at home or abroad;
The right of every family to a decent home;
127
C o n c lu sio
n
The right to adequate medical care and the opportunity to achieve
and enjoy good health;
The right to adequate protection from the economic fears of old
age, sickness, accident, and unemployment;
The right to a good education.
Roosevelt concluded, ‘‘All of these rights spell security. And after
this war is won we must be prepared to move forward, in the
implementation of these rights, to new goals of human happiness
and well-being.’’ 7
Time magazine remarked that ‘‘Dr. Win-the-War has apparently
called into consultation Dr. Win-New-Rights.’’ 8 But many of the
rights—to security from economic hardship, to employment, to
good farm prices, to vigorous business commerce, to a living wage
and a home—already had New Deal programs designed to ensure
their implementation. And others—to medical care and to
education—developed easily from New Deal principles. They
found fuller expression in Roosevelt’s plans for the peace, not only
for America, but for the world. 9
As the New Deal wound down its ambitious domestic program,
the Roosevelt administration began looking outward again.
Secretary of State Cordell Hull, like Keynes, had for decades
believed that an open world economy would tend toward peace
and prosperity. ‘‘[U]nhampered trade,’’ Hull said, ‘‘dovetailed with
peace.’’ 10
To this end he worked to secure trade agreements
including the Anglo-American Trade Agreement of 1938, which
contributed to the idea that international cooperation might
restore the global economy of the era before World War I.
Near the end of World War II, ideas like Hull’s approached fruition.
In June 1944, John Maynard Keynes went to the United States to
represent Britain at the Bretton Woods conference. On paper
Keynes rated as only one of 730 delegates from forty-four countries
128
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
convening to establish rules for the postwar economy. But in person
Keynes played the role of protagonist at the conference. In 1941,
before the United States had entered the war, he had drafted a plan
to supply part of what the Versailles Treaty left out—a system to
ensure the smooth operation of the world’s finance and commerce,
to ‘‘prevent the piling up of credit and debit balances without
limit’’—after all, the cardinal rule for the postwar economy would be
to avoid reproducing the prewar economy. 11 Keynes’s plan for an
International Clearing Union would allot governments credit based
on their share of world trade and allow them to draw that credit,
denominated in a notional banking currency, the Bancor, as needed
to keep their economies stable.
Morally alongside Keynes stood his antagonist, the American
representative Harry Dexter White. White had his own plan to solve
the same problem by slightly different solutions: governments
would still borrow, but from a contributory fund rather than from a
pool of Bancors. 12 White’s plan stood in much the same relation to
Keynes’s idea as the New Deal stood in relation to European welfare
states. Under British programs to address poverty and disability, as
drawn up in the Beveridge plan of 1942, citizens received benefits
from the state as a matter of right. Nobody got pensions as a matter
of right under Social Security—retirees drew benefits because they
had contributed.
The American delegation rejected Keynes’s plan and insisted on
White’s for much the same reason the Roosevelt administration
had insisted on a contributory basis for Social Security: a
contributory scheme would limit claims and satisfy Congress. Thus
White’s plan became the major basis for the International
Monetary Fund (IMF) as agreed at Bretton Woods, and Congress
placed further restrictions on IMF to prevent unconditional
withdrawals from the fund. 13
IMF had a twin, the International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development, better known as the World Bank. Where IMF was
129
C o n c lu sio
n
supposed to allow countries to weather the vicissitudes of free
economies, the World Bank was supposed to lend money for the
repair of war damage and for long-poor countries to enter the club
of modern nations. It stood in relation to the world’s less-
developed regions rather as PWA, TVA, and WPA stood to the
American South and West. Also rather like those New Deal relief
agencies, the World Bank labored under the limits of prevailing
economic opinion, which limited also the bank’s capital: its
first loan to France committed a full third of its available
resources. 14
Even more like the New Deal’s domestic programs, the limited
resources of IMF and the World Bank provided the basis for
experimentation, for discarding failure and building upon success,
surviving even Roosevelt’s death in April 1945. Just as with the
early New Deal, constraints on the early Bretton Woods system
failed to produce global economic recovery: the World Bank could
not supply enough money for reconstruction, and IMF refused to
lend money unless assured it would be used only to correct short-
term imbalances, not for reconstruction at all. 15 And just as in the
New Deal, innovative U.S. policymakers established a new
program to meet the need: in 1947 a State Department official
wrote, ‘‘Communist movements are threatening established
governments in every part of the globe. These movements feed on
economic and political weakness. The countries under Communist
pressure require economic assistance on a large scale if they are to
maintain their territorial integrity and political independence. At
one time it had been expected that the International Bank [for
Reconstruction and Development, i.e., the World Bank] could
satisfy the needs for such assistance. But it is now clear that the
Bank cannot do this job. . . . The only way to meet this challenge is
by a vast new programme of assistance given directly by the United
States itself.’’ 16
This conviction became the basis for the European Recovery
Program, better known as the Marshall Plan, after Secretary of State
130
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
George Marshall, who declared, ‘‘The United States should do
whatever it is able to do to assist in. . . the revival of a working
economy in the world so as to permit the emergence of political and
social conditions in which free institutions can exist.’’ Shortly
afterward, IMF liberalized its lending policy, and the U.S. dollar, still
tied to gold at $35 per ounce, became the base currency of a
revamped Bretton Woods system that lasted for about twenty-five
years. 17
By 1947, thirty years after it entered World War I, the U.S.
government had come around to something approaching Keynes’s
view after Versailles—that as the world’s richest country it had an
obligation to restore the world’s economy to health. The American
leadership reached this conclusion hesitantly and only when
prodded by crisis: they preferred much more modest
experimentation than the brilliant Keynes prescribed. The halting,
piecemeal efforts of the New Deal and then of the Bretton Woods
system solved problems slowly and partially, and thus let the United
States and the world drift rather closer to disaster than a simple
Keynesian move might have done. But the programs met with
ultimate success: Bretton Woods fostered greater economic stability
and more rapid economic growth than eras before or since. 18
The openly experimental, obviously fallible, always compromised
quality of the New Deal programs and their progeny reflected
the imperfect democracy that gave them birth. Considering the
costs of this painful process, we might prefer a program of
comprehensive change to Roosevelt’s caution. But weighing also
the performance of his administration’s jerry-built machinery both
at home and abroad against the record of more sweeping,
ideologically and theoretically coherent programs (including those
that attacked the New Deal), we might better appreciate the
merits of the Roosevelt era’s limits. The New Deal’s evident
imperfection invited criticism and further tinkering, making way
for improvements to the American democracy in the years
afterward and yet to come.
131
C o n c lu sio
n
Notes
1. Michael S. Sherry, The Rise of American Air Power: The Creation of
Armageddon (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1987), 81.
2. ‘‘ The Nine Hundred and Twenty-Ninth Press Conference,’’ The
Public Papers and Addresses of Franklin D. Roosevelt, ed. Samuel
I. Rosenman, 1943, vol., 571.
3. Alan Brinkley, The End of Reform: New Deal Liberalism in
Recession and War (New York: Vintage, 1995), 141.
4. Susan B. Carter et al., eds., Historical Statistics of the United
States, Earliest Times to the Present, Millennial Edition
(New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006), series Ea636
and Ca10.
5. Ibid., series Ba475. Unemployment was 2.89 percent in 1929 and
1.77 percent in 1943.
6. E. Cary Brown, ‘‘Fiscal Policy in the ‘Thirties: A Reappraisal,’’ The
American Economic Review 46, no. 5 (1956): 863–66.
7. ‘‘President Roosevelt’s Message to Congress,’’ New York Times 1/
12/1944, 12.
8. Cited in Cass R. Sunstein, The Second Bill of Rights: FDR’s
Unfinished Revolution and Why We Need It More Than Ever (New
York: Basic Books, 2004), 15.
9. On the question of Roosevelt’s sincerity in this speech, see James
T. Kloppenberg, ‘‘Franklin Delano Roosevelt, Visionary,’’ Reviews
in American History 34, no. 4 (2006).
10. Quoted in Arthur W. Schatz, ‘‘ The Anglo-American Trade
Agreement and Cordell Hull’s Search for Peace 1936–1938,’’
Journal of American History 57, no. 1 (1970).
11. Cited in Elizabeth Borgwardt, A New Deal for the World: America’s
Vision for Human Rights (Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of
Harvard University Press, 2005), 108.
12. See Ibid., 109.
13. Richard N. Gardner, Sterling-Dollar Diplomacy in Current
Perspective: The Origins and Prospects of Our International
Economic Order, New, exp. ed. (New York: Columbia University
Press, 1980), 134–36.
14. Edward S. Mason and Robert E. Asher, The World Bank since
Bretton Woods (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution,
1973), 105.
15. Gardner, Sterling-Dollar, 297.
16. Ibid., 300.
132
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
17. Gardner, Sterling-Dollar, 302.
18. Barry Eichengreen, ‘‘Epilogue: Three Perspectives on the Bretton
Woods System,’’ in A Retrospective on the Bretton Woods System:
Lessons for International Monetary Reform, ed. Michael D. Bordo
and Barry Eichengreen (Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1993), 626.
133
C o n c lu sio
n
Further Reading
Badger, Anthony J. The New Deal: The Depression Years, 1933–40.
London: Macmillan, 1989.
Berlin, Isaiah. ‘‘President Franklin Delano Roosevelt.’’ In The Proper
Study of Mankind: An Anthology of Essays, edited by Henry Hardy
and Roger Hausheer, 628–37. London: Chatto and Windus, 1997.
Bordo, Michael D., Claudia Dale Goldin, and Eugene N. White, eds.
The Defining Moment: The Great Depression and the American
Economy in the Twentieth Century. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1998.
Borgwardt, Elizabeth. A New Deal for the World: America’s Vision for
Human Rights. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard
University Press, 2005.
Brinkley, Alan. The End of Reform: New Deal Liberalism in Recession
and War. New York: Vintage, 1995.
——— . Voices of Protest: Huey Long, Father Coughlin, and the Great
Depression. New York: Vintage, 1983.
Carter, Susan B., Scott Sigmund Gartner, Michael R. Haines, Alan L.
Olmstead, Richard Sutch, and Gavin Wright, eds. Historical
Statistics of the United States, Earliest Times to the Present,
Millennial Edition. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006.
Chandler, Lester V. America’s Greatest Depression, 1929–1941. New
York: Harper and Row, 1970.
Cohen, Andrew Wender. American Monetary Policy, 1928–41. New
York: Harper and Row, 1971.
———— . The Racketeer’s Progress: Chicago and the Struggle for the
Modern American Economy, 1900–1940. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2004.
134
Cohen, Lizabeth. Making a New Deal: Industrial Workers in Chicago,
1919–1939. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.
Eichengreen, Barry. Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great
Depression, 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press, 1992.
——— . ‘‘The Origins and Nature of the Great Slump Revisited.’’
Economic History Review 45, no. 2 (1992): 213–39.
Fearon, Peter. Origins and Nature of the Great Slump, 1929–1932.
Atlantic Highlands, NJ: Humanities Press, 1979.
——— . War, Prosperity, and Depression: The U.S. Economy,
1917–1945. Oxford: Philip Allan, 1987.
Feinstein, Charles H., Peter Temin, and Gianni Toniolo. The European
Economy between the Wars. New York: Oxford University Press,
1997.
Fraser, Steve, and Gary Gerstle, eds. The Rise and Fall of the New Deal
Order, 1930–1980. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989.
Hawley, Ellis W. The New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly: A Study
in Economic Ambivalence. Princeton: Princeton University Press,
1966.
Jacobs, Meg. Pocketbook Politics: Economic Citizenship in Twentieth
Century America. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2005.
Kennedy, David M. Freedom from Fear: The American People in
Depression and War, 1929–1945. New York: Oxford University
Press, 1999.
Kindleberger, Charles Poor. The World in Depression 1929–1939.
London: Allen Lane, 1973.
Leuchtenburg, William E. Franklin D. Roosevelt and the New Deal,
1932–1940. New York: Harper Torchbooks, 1963.
——— . The FDR Years: On Roosevelt and His Legacy. New York:
Columbia University Press, 1995.
——— . The Perils of Prosperity, 1914–1932. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1993.
——— . The Supreme Court Reborn: The Constitutional Revolution in
the Age of Roosevelt. New York: Oxford University Press, 1995.
——— . ‘‘When the People Spoke, What Did They Say?: The Election of
1936 and the Ackerman Thesis.’’ Yale Law Journal 108, no. 8
(1999): 2077–114.
Maher, Neil M. Nature’s New Deal: The Civilian Conservation Corps
and the Roots of the American Environmental Movement. New
York: Oxford University Press, 2007.
135
F u rth
e r R e a d in g
Olson, James S. Saving Capitalism: The Reconstruction Finance
Corporation and the New Deal, 1933–1940. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1988.
Patterson, James T. America’s Struggle against Poverty, 1900–1985.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1986.
——— . Congressional Conservatism and the New Deal: The Growth of
the Conservative Coalition in Congress, 1933–1939. Westport,
CT: Greenwood Press, 1981.
——— . The New Deal and the States: Federalism in Transition.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1969.
Phillips, Sarah T. This Land, This Nation: Conservation, Rural
America, and the New Deal. New York: Cambridge University Press,
2007.
Romer, Christina D. ‘‘The Great Crash and the Onset of the Great
Depression.’’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 105, no. 3 (1990):
597–62.
——— . ‘‘What Ended the Great Depression?’’ Journal of Economic
History 52, no. 4 (1992): 757–84.
Rothermund, Dietmar. The Global Impact of the Great Depression.
London: Routledge, 1996.
Rowley, William D. M. L. Wilson and the Campaign for the Domestic
Allotment. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 1970.
Saloutos, Theodore. ‘‘New Deal Agricultural Policy: An Evaluation.’’
Journal of American History 61, no. 2 (1974): 394–416.
Schulman, Bruce J. From Cotton Belt to Sunbelt: Federal Policy,
Economic Development, and the Transformation of the South,
1938–1980. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 1994.
Skidelsky, Robert. John Maynard Keynes: A Biography. 3 vols.
London: Macmillan, 1983–2000.
Smith, Jason Scott. Building New Deal Liberalism: The Political
Economy of Public Works, 1933–1956. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2006.
Volanto, Keith J. Texas, Cotton, and the New Deal. College Station:
Texas A&M University Press, 2005.
Weir, David R. ‘‘A Century of U.S. Unemployment, 1890–1990:
Revised Estimates and Evidence for Stabilization.’’ Research in
Economic History 14 (1992): 301–46.
136
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Table 1. Major federal acts of the Great Depression and New Deal
Name of action Citation Date Description
Reconstruction Finance Corporation Act
47 Stat. 5 1/23/32 Created Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC), capita- lized at $500m and permitted to issue obligations worth up to three times as much, to aid banks and other industries.
Glass-Steagall Act 47 Stat. 56 2/27/32 Permitted Federal Reserve System to issue notes backed by government securities.
Federal Home Loan Bank Act
47 Stat. 725 7/22/32 Created Home Loan Bank System, patterned on Federal Reserve System, to permit rediscounting of mortgage loans.
Emergency Banking Relief Act
48 Stat. 1 3/9/33 Title I recognized a banking emergency, empowered the president to halt bank transactions and the secretary of the treasury to impound gold. Title II empowered the comptroller of the currency to appoint conservators for banks, investigate their books, and determine their soundness. Title III authorized the RFC to buy and sell bank stock. Title IV liberalized the Federal Reserve System’s authority to issue advances to member banks.
Civilian Conservation Corp Reforestation Relief Act
48 Stat. 22 3/31/33 Authorized the president to create a "conservation corps among the unemployed," which became the Civilian Conservation Corps (CCC), chiefly for the maintenance of public lands.
Agricultural Adjustment Act
48 Stat. 31 5/12/33 Title I recognized a state of agricultural emergency and disparity between rural and urban incomes which it would be
(Continued)
1 3 7
Table 1 (Continued)
Name of action Citation Date Description
policy to redress; directed the secretary of agriculture to create Agricultural Adjustment Administration (AAA) to regulate production of commodities and administer processing tax. Title II, or the Emergency Farm Mortgage Act, expanded fed- eral power to back farm mortgages. Title III, or the Thomas Amendment, authorized the president to issue paper money and determine the gold or silver weight of the dollar.
Federal Emergency Relief Act
48 Stat. 55 5/12/33 Declared an economic emergency of unemployment and failure of local relief funds, allotted $500m of RFC money for a Federal Emer- gency Relief Administration (FERA) to grant as relief to the states.
Tennessee Valley Authority Act
48 Stat. 58 5/18/33 Created the Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA) to maintain and operate Wilson Dam and Muscle Shoals and to improve navi- gationandcontrolfloodsintheregion,extendingtotransmissionof electrical power and manufacture of fertilizer and explosives.
Securities Act of 1933 48 Stat. 74 5/27/33 Required corporations to register securities with the Federal Trade Commission to prevent fraudulent issues.
Home Owners’ Loan Act
48 Stat. 128 6/13/33 Created the Home Owners’ Loan Corporation (HOLC) to refinance mortgages on residences and prevent foreclosures.
Banking Act of 1933 (Glass-Steagall
48 Stat. 162 6/16/33 Increased power of the Federal Reserve Board to oversee transactions of Federal Reserve System, created the temporary
1 3 8
Banking Act) Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), limited com- mercial banks’ ability to trade in securities.
National Industrial Recovery Act
48 Stat. 195 6/16/33 Title I recognized a state of industrial emergency, suspended anti-trust law, and authorized the president to create an agency to address the emergency by the composition of industrial codes; Roosevelt created the National Recovery Administration (NRA). Title II authorized the president to create a Federal Emergency Administration of Public Works, which became the Public Works Administration (PWA), to lend and grant $3.3bn appropriated for this purpose.
Civil Works Administration
Executive Order no. 6420B
11/9/33 Roosevelt created the Civil Works Administration (CWA), funded with $400m from the National Industrial Recovery Act, "for the purpose of increasing employment quickly."
Gold Reserve Act 48 Stat. 337 1/30/34 Placed control of monetary gold in the federal government and authorized the president to establish the gold value of the dollar for a two-year period at not more than 60 percent of its current value; established a stabilization fund in the Treasury.
Securities Exchange Act
48 Stat. 881 6/6/34 Created Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and empowered it to regulate trading of securities on the stock ex- change.
National Housing Act 48 Stat. 1246 6/27/34 Created the Federal Housing Administration (FHA), funded out of the RFC, to insure mortgages.
(Continued)
1 3 9
Table 1 (Continued)
Name of action Citation Date Description
Joint Resolution for Enforcement of National Industrial Recovery Act
48 Stat. 1183 6/19/34 Authorized the president to create a board to enforce section 7a (collective bargaining) of the National Industrial Recovery Act. Roosevelt created the National Labor Relations Board (NLRB).
Emergency Relief Ap- propriation Act of 1935
49 Stat. 115 4/8/35 Appropriated $4.9bn for emergency relief use.
Resettlement Administration
Executive Order no. 7027
4/30/35 Under the Emergency Relief Appropriation Act of 1935, Roosevelt created the Resettlement Administration (RA) to aid the migra- tion of poor farm familes. In 1937 RA became the Farm Security Administration (FSA) within the Department of Agriculture.
Works Progress Administration
Executive Order no. 7034
5/6/35 Under the Emergency Relief Appropriation Act of 1935, Roosevelt created a system for evaluating proposed projects including the Works Progress Administration (WPA), "to move from the relief rolls to work . . . the maximum number of people in the shortest time possible."
Rural Electrification Administration
Executive Order no. 7037
5/11/35 Roosevelt created Rural Electrification Administration (REA) to support the extension of electrical power using funds from the Emergency Relief Appropriation Act of 1935.
1 4 0
National Labor Relations Act (Wagner Act)
49 Stat. 449 7/5/35 Created newNLRB to replace the board created by executive order in 1934, to assure specified rights of employees to organize and bargain collectively and prevent defined unfair labor practices.
Social Security Act 49 Stat. 620 8/14/35 Title I provided for grants to states for old-age assistance. Title II provided for federal old-age benefits. Title III provided for grants to states to administer unemployment compensation plans. Title IV provided grants to states for aid to dependent children. Title V provided grants to states for maternal and child welfare. Title VI allotted money to states for maintaining public health services. Title VII established a Social Security Board to study and recommend "the most effective methods of providing economic security through social insurance." Titles VIII and IX levied taxes on employers and employees to support the program. Title X provided grants to states for aid to the blind.
Banking Act of 1935 49 Stat. 684 8/23/35 Title I made the FDIC permanent. Title II amended the Fed- eral Reserve Act to establish the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, appointed by the president, and lodged powers to regulate the supply of money, establish credit policy, and supervise banks with them.
Public Utilities Holding Company Act
49 Stat. 803 8/26/35 Defined a public interest in public utilites, enumerated abuses of that public interest, and made it policy to eliminate such abuses and also to eliminate holding companies.
(Continued)
1 4 1
Table 1 (Continued)
Name of action Citation Date Description
Soil Conservation and Domestic Allotment Act
49 Stat. 1148 2/20/36 Aimed at achieving agricultural parity through conservation measures.
National Housing Act Amendments of 1938
52 Stat. 8 2/3/38 Amended National Housing Act to make it easier to resell mortgages. RFC created National Mortgage Association of Washington, later renamed the Federal National Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae), to resell mortgages.
Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1938
52 Stat. 31 2/16/38 Established the yardstick of normal wheat yields and paid farmers to meet this target.
Fair Labor Standards Act
52 Stat. 1060 6/25/38 Established national minimum wage and maximum hours, banned child labor.
1 4 2
Index
A AAA (Agricultural Adjustment
Administration), 78–82, 93, 96,
97, 109, 118, 137
AFL (American Federation of
Labor), 82
African Americans, 24, 44, 45, 46,
100, 107, 112, 117
Agee, James, 48
Agricultural Adjustment Act, 77,
137
agriculture. See farms and farming
American Liberty League, 108, 109
Anglo-American Trade Agreement,
128
automotive industry, 13, 14, 19
B Bagehot, Walter, 27, 30
Bank for Reconstruction and
Development. See World Bank
Bankhead Cotton Control Act, 80
Banking Act of 1933, 59, 138
Banking Act of 1935, 62, 141
banking system, 30, 57, 59, 72
banks, 10, 17, 27, 29, 34, 63, 118;
failures of, 19, 29, 30, 31, 56
Baruch, Bernard, 18
Berlin, Isaiah, 1, 5, 56
Black Thursday, 19
Black, John D., 80
Bonus Army, 1, 50–52
Bretton Woods, 6, 128–31
Brown, E. Cary, 127
C Carr, E. H., 11
CCC (Civilian Conservation Corps),
64, 66, 90, 108, 126, 137
CES (Committee on Economic
Security), 97, 98, 102
charities, 41
Clayton Act, 82
communism,50,51,110,112,120,130
Consumers Advisory Board, 96
consumer spending, 13, 15, 19, 82
consumers’ unions, 96, 97
corruption, 68, 84
countervailing power, 5, 87, 88, 92,
95–97, 102, 118
court-packing, 113, 114
CWA (Civil Works Administration),
66–67, 139
Coolidge, Calvin, 23, 76, 89
Coughlin, Charles. See Father
Coughlin
credit, purchasing on, 13–15, 18, 19
143
D Darrow, Clarence, 25, 84
debt: personal, 13, 15, 28, 47, 60,
62, 74; intergovernmental, 10, 12,
15, 27–29, 33, 60. See also
monetary policy
depressions and recessions, 5, 12,
29, 38, 47, 57, 115. See also Great
Depression
Dies, Martin, 120
dust bowl, 47
E economic growth, 1, 5, 12–15, 57,
131
elections: of 1928, 23, 25; of 1930,
31; of 1932, 35, 52, 89, 105; of
1936, 102, 106, 108, 110–12; of
1938, 117, 126
Emergency Banking Act, 57,
61, 62
Emergency Relief and Construction
Act, 63
European Recovery Program. See
Marshall Plan
Evans, Walker, 48
F Fair Labor Standards Act, 116, 126,
142
Father Coughlin, 49, 50, 112
Farrell, James, 32
farm policy, 73–79
farms and farming, 28, 46, 47, 56,
62, 73–76, 78, 79
FDIC (Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation), 59, 139, 141
Federal Art Project, 120
FederalEmergencyReliefAct,65,137
Federal Employment Stabilization
Board, 32
Federal Farm Board, 77
Federal Land Bank system, 34
Federal Relief Appropriation Act,
67, 140
Federal Reserve System, 1, 3, 17, 27,
28, 30, 34, 57, 59, 61, 62, 137, 138,
141
Federal Theatre Project, 120, 121
Federal Writers’ Project, 119
FERA (Federal Emergency Relief
Administration), 65–67, 137
fiscal policy, 5, 12, 26, 29, 33, 65, 66,
67, 93, 115, 116, 126, 127
G Galbraith, John Kenneth, 87
global finance, 18, 20, 130
Gold Reserve Act, 62
gold standard, 59–62
Great Crash, 3, 18, 19, 28, 30, 40,
44, 47, 50, 77
Great Depression, 2, 3, 8, 19, 25, 38,
46, 48–50, 65, 69, 73, 101, 111,
126
Guffey Coal Act, 110
H Harburg, E. Y., 39
Harrison, George L., 28
health insurance, 102
Hickok, Lorena, 48
hoboes, 44, 64
Hofstadter, Richard, 10
Home Loan Banks, 34, 137
Homestead Act, 73
Hoover, Herbert, 3, 6, 17, 20,
23–35, 50–52, 61, 63, 76, 82, 105,
107, 111; and 1927 flood relief, 23,
24; relief philosophy of, 24–26,
31, 32, 35; responses to Crash of,
26, 31–34, 63
Hoovervilles, 44, 45
Hopkins, Harry, 65–68, 99, 108
Howe, Frederic, 96
144
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Hughes, Charles Evans, 16, 108
Hull, Cordell, 128
I Ickes, Harold, 65
IMF (International Monetary
Fund), 129, 130
immigration and immigration
policy, 9, 11, 12, 33, 38, 68
industrial policy, 81–84
J Johnson, Hugh, 76, 81, 83
K Kennedy, David M., 2
Kennedy, Joseph P., 18, 20, 62
Keynesianism, 118
Keynes, John Maynard, 8–11, 19,
20, 115, 116, 126, 128, 129, 131
L Lamont, Thomas, 29
Lange, Dorothea, 48
Laval, Pierre, 61
League of Nations, 11
Lilienthal, David, 90, 91
London Economic Conference, 72
M MacArthur, Douglas, 51
Marshall, George, 131
Marshall Plan, 130, 131
McNary-Haugen bills, 76, 77
McReynolds, James, 113
Mencken, H. L., 25
Mills, Ogden, 34
Moley, Raymond, 59, 77
monetary policy, 17, 18, 27–30, 34,
56, 59, 61, 62, 72, 118, 129
Morehead v. New York ex. rel.
Tipaldo, 110
Morgenthau, Henry, 126
Morrill Land Grant Act, 74
municipal assistance, 42, 43, 49
N NAACP (National Association for
the Advancement of Colored
People), 107
National Consumers’ League, 116
National Labor Relations Act, 105
National Industrial Recovery Act,
82, 95, 96, 110, 140
National Resources Planning
Board, 118
New Deal, 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 56–69,
72,77,78,82,87,88,91,94,97,101,
102, 106, 109, 111, 114, 116, 121,
126, 127, 130; approval/
disapproval of, 62, 64, 67–9,
78, 111; criticism and
opponents of, 92, 106, 108–10,
113–18, 120; failures of, 66, 72,
84, 85, 93, 95, 116, 117, 131;
major acts of, 137–42;
methodology of, 1, 4, 6, 56–58,
67, 131; opposition to, 120;
successes of, 57, 68, 91, 92, 93, 102,
117–20, 131
NLRB (National Labor Relations
Board), 94, 95, 120, 140, 141
NRA (National Recovery
Administration), 81, 83, 84, 94,
96, 108–110
O optimism, 18, 19, 25, 26, 31, 115
P Peek, George, 76, 78, 81
Pacific Railroad Act, 73
145
In d e x
Patton, George S., 51
Perkins, Frances, 82, 84
political economy, 6, 70, 85, 88–90,
92, 93, 97, 102, 118
price-fixing, 81–84
PWA (Public Works
Administration), 65, 66, 91,
92, 130
R racism, 24, 38, 40, 44–46, 92, 93,
100, 107, 117
recovery, 57, 72, 80–82, 85, 102,
relief, 4, 57, 63–66, 67–9, 82, 116;
attitudes toward public, 39, 41,
42, 49, 65, 67, 69, 126; federal
efforts for aimed directly at
public, 4, 13, 35, 63–66, 116;
non–New Deal federal efforts for,
32–34, 63; private efforts for, 32;
state and local efforts for, 26, 27,
32, 42, 49, 65, 68; work relief,
64–67, 82, 115, 116, 126
reflation, 4, 56, 59, 61, 62, 69
REA (Rural Electrification
Administration), 91, 140
Revenue Act, 93
RFC (Reconstruction Finance
Corporation), 34, 50, 57, 62, 63,
66, 137
Roberts, Owen, 114
Rockefeller, John D., 19
Roosevelt, Franklin D., 1, 2, 4–6,
16, 20, 56–69, 77, 78, 82–89,
92, 94, 98, 101, 102, 105, 115,
116, 126, 131; as governor of
New York, 32, 35, 52; and
the Supreme Court, 109,
110–14; after the new deal,
126–31; campaigning and
elections, 2, 5, 35, 52, 77, 89,
102; conservatism of 59, 66,
106, 110, 111, 115; in the navy,
24, 88
Rumsey, Mary Harriman, 96
S Schecter v. United States, 108
Schumpeter, Joseph, 19
Schwellenbach, Lewis, 87
SEC (Securities and Exchange
Commission), 62, 139
sectionalism, 74–76, 90, 91, 100,
111, 113, 117
sexism, 44, 45
sharecropping, 48, 119
Smoot-Hawley Tariff, 28
Social Security, 98, 99–101, 106,
114, 118, 129
Social Security Act, 114
socialism, 32, 78, 85, 90
speculation, 16, 17
state power, 85, 95, 96, 101, 102,
107
strikes, 94
stock market, 15–17
stock pools, 16
Supreme Court, 82, 95, 108–11, 113,
114, 118
T tariffs, 10, 11, 12, 28, 29, 60, 74, 76,
77
tax policy, 31, 74, 80, 93, 94, 99
Terkel, Studs, 5
Thomas Amendment, 61, 62
TNEC (Temporary National
Economic Committee), 116
trade policy, 9, 10, 28, 29
Trading with the Enemy Act, 57, 58
tramps. See hoboes
Treaty of Versailles, 8, 9, 11,
129, 131
146
T h e G re a t D e p re ss io n a n d th e N e w
D e a l
Truman, Harry S, 117
TVA (Tennessee Valley Authority),
89–91, 118, 130, 138
U Un-American Activities
Committee, 120
underemployment. 40
unemployment, 1, 5, 15, 26, 31–33,
40, 46, 55, 57, 64, 67, 96, 97, 101,
102, 115 126
unions, 32, 41, 82–4, 94–97, 116,
120
V veterans. See Bonus Army
W
wages, 13, 14, 26, 69, 82, 95, 116
Wagner, Robert, 95
Wagner Act, 95, 96, 110,
114, 141
Wallace, Henry A., 76, 78, 85
West Coast Hotel v. Parrish, 114
White, Harry Dexter, 129
White, Walter, 107
WIB (War Industries Board), 76,
81, 83
Wilson, Milburn L., 77, 78
Willkie, Wendell, 91
World Bank, 129, 130
world economy, 6, 20, 29, 72,
128, 130; pre-WWI system, 8, 9,
10, 11, 128; international trade,
28, 29; overseas investment,
17, 62
World Economic Conference, 11, 12
World War I, 4, 7, 8, 9, 11, 12, 38,
72, 75–77, 88, 128
World War II, 5, 65, 126, 128
WPA (Works Progress
Administration), 67, 68, 93,
108, 117, 118, 120, 122, 126,
130, 140
147
In d e x
Expand your collection of
VERY SHORT INTRODUCTIONS
1. Classics
2. Music
3. Buddhism
4. Literary Theory
5. Hinduism
6. Psychology
7. Islam
8. Politics
9. Theology
10. Archaeology
11. Judaism
12. Sociology
13. The Koran
14. The Bible
15. Social and Cultural
Anthropology
16. History
17. Roman Britain
18. The Anglo-Saxon Age
19. Medieval Britain
20. The Tudors
21. Stuart Britain
22. Eighteenth-Century Britain
23. Nineteenth-Century Britain
24. Twentieth-Century Britain
25. Heidegger
26. Ancient Philosophy
27. Socrates
28. Marx
29. Logic
30. Descartes
31. Machiavelli
32. Aristotle
33. Hume
34. Nietzsche
35. Darwin
36. The European Union
37. Gandhi
38. Augustine
39. Intelligence
40. Jung
41. Buddha
42. Paul
43. Continental Philosophy
44. Galileo
45. Freud
46. Wittgenstein
47. Indian Philosophy
48. Rousseau
49. Hegel
50. Kant
51. Cosmology
52. Drugs
53. Russian Literature
54. The French Revolution
55. Philosophy
56. Barthes
57. Animal Rights
58. Kierkegaard
59. Russell
60. Shakespeare
61. Clausewitz
62. Schopenhauer
63. The Russian Revolution
64. Hobbes
65. World Music
66. Mathematics
67. Philosophy of Science
68. Cryptography
69. Quantum Theory
70. Spinoza
71. Choice Theory
148
72. Architecture
73. Poststructuralism
74. Postmodernism
75. Democracy
76. Empire
77. Fascism
78. Terrorism
79. Plato
80. Ethics
81. Emotion
82. Northern Ireland
83. Art Theory
84. Locke
85. Modern Ireland
86. Globalization
87. Cold War
88. The History of
Astronomy
89. Schizophrenia
90. The Earth
91. Engels
92. British Politics
93. Linguistics
94. The Celts
95. Ideology
96. Prehistory
97. Political Philosophy
98. Postcolonialism
99. Atheism
100. Evolution
101. Molecules
102. Art History
103. Presocratic Philosophy
104. The Elements
105. Dada and Surrealism
106. Egyptian Myth
107. Christian Art
108. Capitalism
109. Particle Physics
110. Free Will
111. Myth
112. Ancient Egypt
113. Hieroglyphs
114. Medical Ethics
115. Kafka
116. Anarchism
117. Ancient Warfare
118. Global Warming
119. Christianity
120. Modern Art
121. Consciousness
122. Foucault
123. Spanish Civil War
124. The Marquis de Sade
125. Habermas
126. Socialism
127. Dreaming
128. Dinosaurs
129. Renaissance Art
130. Buddhist Ethics
131. Tragedy
132. Sikhism
133. The History of Time
134. Nationalism
135. The World Trade
Organization
136. Design
137. The Vikings
138. Fossils
139. Journalism
140. The Crusades
141. Feminism
142. Human Evolution
143. The Dead Sea Scrolls
144. The Brain
145. Global Catastrophes
146. Contemporary Art
147. Philosophy of Law
148. The Renaissance
149. Anglicanism
150. The Roman Empire
151. Photography
149
152. Psychiatry
153. Existentialism
154. The First World War
155. Fundamentalism
156. Economics
157. International Migration
158. Newton
159. Chaos
160. African History
161. Racism
162. Kabbalah
163. Human Rights
164. International Relations
165. The American
Presidency
166. The Great Depression
and The New Deal
167. Classical Mythology
168. The New Testament as
Literature
169. American Political
Parties and Elections
170. Bestsellers
171. Geopolitics
172. Antisemitism
173. Game Theory
174. HIV/AIDS
175. Documentary Film
176. Modern China
177. The Quakers
178. German Literature
179. Nuclear Weapons
180. Law
181. The Old Testament
150
Download more eBooks here: http://avaxhome.ws/blogs/ChrisRedfield
- Cover
- Title page
- Contents
- Acknowledgments
- List of Illustrations
- Introduction
- Chapter 1: The World in Debt
- Chapter 2: The Hoover Years
- Chapter 3: Americans in the Depression
- Chapter 4: Reflation and Relief
- Chapter 5: Managing Farm and Factory
- Chapter 6: Countervailing Power
- Chapter 7: The End of the Beginning
- Conclusion: The New American Way at Home and Around the World
- Further Reading
- Index

Get help from top-rated tutors in any subject.
Efficiently complete your homework and academic assignments by getting help from the experts at homeworkarchive.com