South University
file:///C|/Users/CWATKIM/Desktop/Competitive%20Advantage.html[7/1/2020 10:16:24 PM]
Competitive Advantage Due to an increasing focus on contributing to the company’s competitive advantage, training departments will have to evolve. The training departments must shift focus to the performance analysis approach, which involves identifying performance gaps/deficiencies and using training as a solution.
Training departments need involvement via:
Focusing on interventions related to performance improvement Providing support for high-performance work systems Developing systems for training administration, development, and delivery that reduce costs and increase employee access to learning
When moving to high-performance work systems, training departments need to provide training for interpersonal, quality, and technical skills in ways that promote aspects of the customer-service system or the production system.
In order to improve business performance, companies are purchasing learning management systems (LMSs) that provide training administration, development tools, and online training. The LMSs are changing from providing/tracking training to focusing on talent management. They include more career planning tools to help connect employees with different development resources. The LMSs also include performance evaluations to identify skill gaps.
Cloud computing refers to a computing system that provides information technology infrastructure over a network in a self-service, modifiable, and on-demand context. Cloud computing allows groups to work together in new ways, enhances productivity by allowing employees to access information more easily, and provides greater access to large company databases. Workforce analytics tools, training and development programs, and social media resources will be more easily accessible and available for use.
Interest in big data related to training will continue to grow, which involves collecting data about users’ activities, analyzing or mining the data to identify patterns and trends, and understanding how these patterns and trends link to business goals. The data can be useful for identifying how employees learn, who the experts and leaders in social networks are, and which instructions lead to positive reactions from learners and results.
Trainers must identify partners for outsourcing that can deliver efficient/effective training solutions, particularly technology based.
How to Choose the Right LMS for a Company
Let’s assume that you are the CEO or chief HRM officer of the Ruth L. Jennings Submarine Manufacturing company, incorporated. Based on the environment, you find that you will need to implement a learning management system (LMS). What should you know prior to choosing one?
Review the criteria to learn more.
Reference Noe, R. A. (2012). Employee training and development (6th ed.). New York, NY: McGraw-Hill Education.
South University
file:///C|/Users/CWATKIM/Desktop/Competitive%20Advantage.html[7/1/2020 10:16:24 PM]
Additional Materials
From your course textbook, Employee Training and Development, read the following chapters:
Traditional Training Methods Technology-Based Training Methods Employee Development and Career Management Social Responsibility: Legal Issues, Managing Diversity, and Career Challenges The Future of Training and Development
- Local Disk
- South University
Managerial Economics and Strategy
Third Edition
Chapter 3
Empirical Methods for Demand Analysis
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
If this PowerPoint presentation contains mathematical equations, you may need to check that your computer has the following installed:
1) MathType Plugin
2) Math Player (free versions available)
3) NVDA Reader (free versions available)
1
Managerial Problem
Estimating the Effect of an iTunes Price Change
How can managers use the data to estimate the demand curve facing iTunes? How can managers determine if a price increase is likely to raise revenue, even though the quantity demanded will fall?
Solution Approach
Managers can use empirical methods to analyze economic relationships that affect a firm’s demand.
Empirical Methods
Elasticity measures the responsiveness of one variable, such as quantity demanded, to a change in another variable, such as price.
Regression analysis is a method to estimate a relationship between a dependent variable (quantity demanded) and explanatory variables (price and income). It requires identifying the properties and statistical significance of estimated coefficients, as well as model identification.
Forecasting is the use of regression analysis to predict future values of important variables as sales or revenue.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Learning Objectives (1 of 2)
3.1 Elasticity
Calculate elasticities and apply them to managerial problems
Regression Analysis
3.2 Use regression analysis to estimate business relationships
3.3 Properties and Statistical Significance of Estimated Coefficients
Determine the confidence we can place in a regression analysis
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Learning Objectives (2 of 2)
3.4 Regression Specification
Explain how to choose an appropriate regression specification
3.5 Forecasting
Forecast important business variables using regression analysis
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.1 Elasticity (1 of 9)
The Price Elasticity of Demand
The price elasticity of demand (or elasticity of demand or demand elasticity) is the percentage change in quantity demanded, Q, divided by the percentage change in price, p.
Arc Elasticity:
It is an elasticity that uses the average quantity,
and average price,
as the denominators for percentage calculations.
In the formula
is the percentage change in quantity demanded and
is the percentage change in price.
Arc elasticity is based on a discrete change between two distinct price-quantity combinations on a demand curve.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.1 Elasticity (2 of 9)
Managerial Implication:
Changing Prices to Calculate an Arc Elasticity
One of the easiest and most straightforward ways for a manager to determine the elasticity of demand for a firm’s product is to conduct an experiment.
If the firm is a price setter and can vary the price of its product, the manager can change the price and observe how the quantity sold varies.
Armed with two observations—the quantity sold at the original price and the quantity sold at the new price—the manager can calculate an arc elasticity.
Depending on the size of the calculated elasticity, the manager may continue to sell at the new price or revert to the original price.
It is often possible to obtain useful information from an experiment in a few markets or even just one small submarket—in one country, in one city, or even in one supermarket.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.1 Elasticity (3 of 9)
Point Elasticity:
Point elasticity measures the effect of a small change in price on the quantity demanded.
In the formula, we are evaluating the elasticity at the point (Q, p) and
is the ratio of the change in quantity to the change in price.
Point elasticity is useful when the entire demand information is available.
Point Elasticity with Calculus:
To use calculus, the change in price becomes very small.
the ratio
converges to the derivative
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.1 Elasticity (4 of 9)
Elasticity Along the Demand Curve
The elasticity of demand is different at every point along a downward-sloping linear demand curve.
However, horizontal and vertical demand curves, which are extreme cases of a linear demand curve, have the same elasticity at every point.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.1 Elasticity (5 of 9)
Downward-Sloping Linear Demand Curves
If the shape of the linear demand curve is downward sloping, elasticity varies along the demand curve.
The elasticity of demand is a more negative number the higher the price and hence the smaller the quantity.
In Figure 3.1, the higher the price, the more elastic the demand curve. A 1% increase in price causes a larger percentage fall in quantity near the top of the demand curve than near the bottom.
The coffee demand curve is perfectly elastic
where the demand curve
hits the vertical axis at $12 per l b.
It is elastic (ε < −1) for high prices below $12 and above $6 per lb.
It has unitary elasticity (ε = −1) at the midpoint.
It is inelastic (ε = 0) for low prices below $6 and above $0 per lb.
It is perfectly inelastic (ε = 0) where the demand curve hits the horizontal axis at $0 per l b.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.1 The Elasticity of Demand Varies Along the Linear Coffee Demand Curve
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.1 Elasticity (6 of 9)
Horizontal Demand Curves:
at every point
If the price increases even slightly, demand falls to zero. In Figure 3.2, panel a, the demand is horizontal at p*.
The demand curve is perfectly elastic: a small increase in price causes an infinite drop in quantity.
Why would a good’s demand curve be horizontal? One reason is that consumers view this good as identical to another good and do not care which one they buy.
Vertical Demand Curves: ε = 0 at every point
If the price goes up, the quantity demanded is unchanged, so ∆Q=0. In Figure 3.2, panel b, the demand is vertical at Q*.
The demand curve is perfectly inelastic.
A demand curve is vertical for essential goods—goods that people feel they must have and will pay anything to get it.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.2 Vertical and Horizontal Demand Curves
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.1 Elasticity (7 of 9)
Other Types of Demand Elasticities
Income Elasticity of Demand,
Income elasticity is the percentage change in the quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in income Y.
Normal goods have positive income elasticity, such as coffee.
Inferior goods have negative income elasticity, such as instant soup.
Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand,
Cross-price elasticity is the percentage change in the quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in the price of another good, p o
Complement goods have negative cross-price elasticity, such as cream and coffee.
Substitute goods have positive cross-price elasticity, such as cotton and wool.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.1 Elasticity (8 of 9)
Demand Elasticities over Time
The shape of a demand curve depends on the time period under consideration.
It is easy to substitute between products in the long run but not in the short run.
Liddle (2012) estimated gasoline demand elasticities across many countries and found that the short-run elasticity was −0.16, and the long-run elasticity was −0.43.
Other Elasticities
The relationship between any two related variables can be summarized by an elasticity. A manager might be interested in:
The price elasticity of supply—percentage increase in quantity supplied arising from a 1% increase in price.
Or, the elasticity of cost with respect to output—percentage increase in cost arising from a 1% increase in output.
Or, during labor negotiations, the elasticity of output with respect to labor—the percentage increase in output arising from a 1% increase in labor input, holding other inputs constant.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.1 Elasticity (9 of 9)
Estimating Demand Elasticities
Managers use price, income, and cross-price elasticities to set prices.
To calculate an arc elasticity, managers use data from before and after the price change.
By comparing quantities just before and just after a price change, managers can be reasonably sure that other variables, such as income, have not changed appreciably.
A manager might want an estimate of the demand elasticity before actually making a price change to avoid a potentially expensive mistake.
A manager may fear a reaction by a rival firm in response to a pricing experiment, so they would like to have demand elasticity in advance.
A manager would like to know the effect on demand of many possible price changes rather than focusing on just one price change.
However, managers might need an estimate of the entire demand curve to have demand elasticities before making any real price change. The tool needed is regression analysis.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.2 Regression Analysis (1 of 6)
A regression analysis is a statistical technique used to estimate the relationship between a dependent variable and explanatory variables.
A Demand Function Example
Demand Function: Q = a + b p + e
Quantity is a function of price; Q to the left is the dependent variable; p to the right is the explanatory variable; e is the random error (unpredictable and unobservable effects on dependent variable).
It is a linear demand and the estimated sign of b must be negative
If a manager surveys customers about how many units they will buy at various prices, he is using data to estimate the demand function.
Inverse Demand Function: p = g + h Q + e
Price is a function of quantity; p to the left is the dependent variable; Q to the right is the explanatory variable; e is the random error.
Based on the previous demand function, so
and has a specific linear form. The sign of h must be negative
If a manager surveys how much customers were willing to pay for various units of a product or service, he would estimate the inverse demand equation.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.2 Regression Analysis (2 of 6)
Regression Analysis Using Microsoft Excel
Portland Fish Inverse Demand Function: p = g + h Q + e
g and h are true coefficients.
Inverse Demand Function Estimation:
The O L S regression provides estimates of these coefficients,
which we can use to predict the expected price,
for a given quantity. It is
assumed e=0.
Use Microsoft Excel Trendline option for scatterplots to estimate
using O L S and get the respective graph and function (steps next).
The estimated inverse demand curve is
The estimated change in price needed to induce buyers to purchase one more
unit (1,000 libras) is
Ordinary Least Squares (O L S) Regression
O L S is the most common regression method. It fits the line to minimize the sum of the squared residuals, as shown in Figure 3.4
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.4 An Estimated Demand Curve for Cod at the Portland Fish Exchange
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.2 Regression Analysis (3 of 6)
Microsoft Excel Trendline Option for Scatterplots
Steps Inverse Demand Function Estimation:
Enter the quantity data in column A and the price data in column B
Select the data, click on the Insert tab, and select the “Insert Scatter (X, Y) or Bubble Chart” option in the Chart area of the toolbar. A menu of scatterplot types will appear (Excel Screenshots, panel a)
Click “Scatter.” A chart appears in the spreadsheet.
Click on the plus sign to obtain the Chart Elements menu.
Place the cursor over the Trendline option and click on the arrow beside it to show an additional menu. Click on More Options. A Format Trendline dialog box opens to the right.
Select the options “Linear,” “Display Equation on chart,” and “Display R-squared value on chart” (Excel Screenshots, panel b).
The estimated regression line appears in the diagram. By default, Excel refers to the variable on the vertical axis as y (which is our p) and the variable on the horizontal axis as x (which is our Q).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Microsoft Excel Screenshots (Windows Version 2016) (1 of 2)
a) Scatter Options
b) Trendline Estimation
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.2 Regression Analysis (4 of 6)
Multivariate Regression: p = g + h Q + i3Y + e
Multivariate Regression is a regression with two or more explanatory variables.
The inverse demand function above incorporates both quantity Q and income Y as explanatory variables.
g, h, and i are coefficients to be estimated, and e is a random error.
Corresponding Estimated Regression:
are the estimated coefficients and
is the predicted value of p
for any given levels of Q and Y.
The objective of an O L S multivariate regression is to fit the data so that the sum of squared residuals is as small as possible.
A multivariate regression is able to isolate the effects of each explanatory variable holding the other explanatory variables constant.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.2 Regression Analysis (5 of 6)
Goodness of Fit and the
Statistic
The
(R-squared) statistic is a measure of the goodness of fit of the regression
line to the data.
The
statistic is the share of the dependent variable’s variation that is
explained by the regression.
The
statistic must lie between 0 and 1.
1 indicates that 100% of the variation in the dependent variable is explained by the regression.
Figure 3.5 shows two apple pie demand regressions for two different cities.
Data points in panel a are close to the linear estimated demand, while they are more widely scattered in panel b.
in panel a and
in panel b.
Mai, the bakery owner, is more confident that she can predict the effect of a price change in the first town (panel a) than in the second (panel b).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.5 Two Estimated Apple Pie Demand Curves with Different R-squared Statistics
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.2 Regression Analysis (6 of 6)
Managerial Implication: Focus Groups
Managers interested in estimating market demand curves often can obtain data from published sources, as in our Portland Fish Exchange example.
However, if managers want to estimate the demand function for their own individual firm, they must collect information about how many units customers would demand at various prices.
They can hire a specialized marketing firm to recruit and question a focus group (a number of actual or potential consumers).
Alternatively, the marketing firm might conduct an online or written survey of potential customers designed to elicit similar information.
Managers should use a focus group if it’s the least costly method of learning about the demand curve they face.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.3 Properties and Statistical Significance of Estimated Coefficients
There are key questions when estimating coefficients:
How close are the estimated coefficients of the demand equation to
the true values, for instance
respect to the true value a?
How are the estimates based on a sample reflecting the true values of the entire population?
Are the sample estimates on target?
Repeated Samples
The intuition underlying statistical measures of confidence and significance is based on repeated samples.
We trust the regression results if the estimated coefficients were the same or very close for regressions performed with repeated samples.
However, it is costly, difficult, or impossible to gather repeated samples to assess the reliability of regression estimates.
So, we focus on the properties of both estimating methods and estimated coefficients.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.3 Properties and Significance of Coefficients (1 of 5)
Desirable Properties for Estimated Coefficients
Ordinary Least Squares estimation method (O L S) is an unbiased estimation method under mild conditions.
It produces an estimated coefficient,
that equals the true coefficient,
a, on average.
O L S is a consistent estimation method.
O L S produces consistent estimates that vary less than other relevant unbiased estimation methods under a wide range of conditions.
The smaller the standard error of an estimated coefficient, the smaller the expected variation in the estimates obtained from different samples.
Each estimated coefficient has a standard error.
We use the standard error to evaluate the significance of estimated coefficients.
We prefer a small standard error.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.3 Properties and Significance of Coefficients (2 of 5)
A Focus Group Example
Estimate a linear D curve for Toyota Camry cars, Q = a + b p + e
A focus group of 50 potential buyers are asked about their willingness to buy Camry’s at prices from $5,000 to $40,000.
We use O L S using Microsoft Excel’s Regression tool in the Data tab (steps in next slide).
The estimated D curve is = 53.857 − 1.438p
The estimate of b is −1.438, and its estimated standard error is 0.090.
The estimate for a is 53.857, and its estimated standard error is 2.260.
is 0.977. This high
indicates that the regression line explains almost
all the variation in the observed quantity.
Use the estimated D to estimate the q for any p
If the price is
we expect the focus group consumers to buy 15 cars
If this focus group represented a large group, perhaps a thousand times larger, the quantity demanded estimate would be 15,031 cars.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.3 Properties and Significance of Coefficients (3 of 5)
Using Microsoft Excel’s Regression Tool
Steps Linear Demand Function Estimation: Q = a + b p + e
Verify you have Data Analysis under Data. If not, install Analysis ToolPak:
(Screenshots, panel a)
Enter your data, click on the Data tab, then on the Data Analysis icon. The Data Analysis dialog box displays. Select “Regression” and click OK (Screenshots, panel b)
In the Regression dialog, fill in the Input Y Range field (dependent variable), the Input X Range field (explanatory variable) and enter A22 in the box for the Output Range button (Screenshots, panel c). Then, click OK.
Excel displays results starting in cell A22 with a Summary Output. The regression is Q = 53.857 − 1.438p. If the price is 27, we expect consumers to buy Q = 53.857 − 1.438p = 15.03 Camrys.
The
very high. Excel also displays standard errors and confidence
intervals.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Microsoft Excel Screenshots (Windows Version 2016) (2 of 2)
a) Analysis ToolPak
b) Data Analysis Box
c) Regression Box
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.3 Properties and Significance of Coefficients (4 of 5)
Confidence Intervals
A confidence interval provides a range of likely values for the true value of a coefficient, centered on the estimated coefficient.
A 95% confidence interval is a range of coefficient values such that there is a 95% probability that the true value of the coefficient lies in the specified interval.
Simple Rule for Confidence Intervals
In regressions with large sample sizes, the 95% confidence interval is approximately the estimated coefficient minus/plus twice its estimated standard error.
With smaller sample sizes, the confidence interval is larger and its calculation needs a t-statistic distribution table.
If the confidence interval is small, then we are reasonably sure that the true parameter lies close to the estimated coefficient. Having a larger data set tends to increase our confidence in our results.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.3 Properties and Significance of Coefficients (5 of 5)
Hypothesis Testing and Statistical Significance
Null Hypothesis Problem
Suppose a firm’s manager runs a regression where the demand for the firm’s product is a function of the product’s price and the prices charged by several possible rivals.
If the true coefficient on a rival’s price is 0, the manager can ignore that firm when making decisions.
Thus, the manager wants to formally test the null hypothesis that the rival’s coefficient is 0.
Testing Approach Using the t-statistic
The t-statistic equals the estimated coefficient divided by its estimated standard error. That is, the t-statistic measures whether the estimated coefficient is large relative to the standard error.
In a large sample, if the t-statistic > 2, we reject the null hypothesis that the proposed explanatory variable has no effect at the 5% significance level or 95% confidence level.
Most analysts would just say the explanatory variable is statistically significant.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.4 Regression Specification (1 of 6)
Regression specification is the first step in a regression analysis.
It includes the choice of the dependent variable, the explanatory variables, and the functional relationship between them (linear, quadratic, or exponential).
Selecting Explanatory Variables
A regression analysis is valid only if the regression equation is correctly specified.
It should include all the observable variables that are likely to have a meaningful effect on the dependent variable.
It must closely approximate the true functional form.
The underlying assumptions about the error term should be correct.
We use our understanding of causal relationships, including those that derive from economic theory, to select explanatory variables.
See an application in the next slide.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.4 Regression Specification (2 of 6)
Selecting Variables, Mini Case: Determinants of C E O Compensation
Y = a + b A + c L + d S + f X + e
The dependent variable, Y, is C E O compensation in 000 of dollars.
Explanatory variables are assets A, number of workers L, average return on stocks S, and C E O’s experience X.
O L S regression is
t-statistics for the coefficients of A, L, S, and X are 10.1, 8.77, 5.25, and 3.40, respectively.
Based on these t-statistics, all four variables are “statistically significant.”
Although these variables are statistically significantly different than zero, not all of them are economically significant.
For instance, S is statistically significant but its effect on C E O’s compensation is very small: one percentage point increase of shareholder return would add $35,000 per year to the C E O’s wage.
So, S is statistically significant but economically not very important.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.4 Regression Specification (3 of 6)
Correlation and Causation is a Common Confusion
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.4 Regression Specification (4 of 6)
Correlation and Causation—Common Confusion
Two variables are correlated if they move together. However, correlation does not necessarily imply causation.
The q demanded and p are negatively correlated: p goes up, q goes down. This correlation is causal, changes in p directly affect q.
Sales of gasoline and the incidence of sunburn are positively correlated, but one doesn’t cause the other.
Thus, it is critical that we do not include explanatory variables that have only a spurious relationship to the dependent variable in a regression equation. In estimating gasoline demand, we would include price, income, sunshine hours, but never sunburn incidence.
Omitted Variables
These are variables not included in the regression specification because of lack of information. So, there is not too much a manager can do.
However, if one or more key explanatory variables are missing, then the resulting coefficient estimates and hypothesis tests may be unreliable.
A low
may signal the presence of omitted variables, but theory and logic must
determine what key variables are missing.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.4 Regression Specification (5 of 6)
Functional Form
We cannot assume that demand curves or other economic relationships are always linear.
Choosing the correct functional form may be difficult.
One useful step, especially if there is only one explanatory variable, is to plot the data and the estimated regression line for each functional form under consideration.
Graphical Presentation in Figure 3.6
Panel a shows a linear regression line of the form Q = a + b A + e
Panel b shows a quadratic regression curve of the form
Linear form:
Quadratic form:
The quadratic regression in panel b fits better than the linear regression in panel a.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.6 The Effect of Advertising on Demand
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.4 Regression Specification (6 of 6)
Managerial Implication: Experiments
Many firms use controlled experiments.
For example, a firm can vary its price and observe how consumers react. Unfortunately, the firm cannot control other variables that affect consumer reactions.
So, firms often use regressions to hold constant some variables that they could not control explicitly and to analyze their results.
Harrah’s Entertainment relies its marketing on randomized tests of various hypotheses (compares answers from test and control groups).
Google shows on its website how a firm can run randomized experiments on the effectiveness of advertising while controlling for geographic or other differences.
Managers can benefit from running experiments, particularly if they can make use of low-cost internet experiments, as Amazon, Facebook, Netflix, Google, and others do.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.5 Forecasting (1 of 4)
Extrapolation
Extrapolation seeks to forecast a variable as a function of time.
Extrapolation starts with a series of observations called time series.
The time series is smoothed in some way to reveal the underlying pattern, and this pattern is then extrapolated into the future.
Two linear smoothing techniques are trend line and seasonal variation.
Not all time trends are linear.
Trends
Trend line: R = a + b t + e, where t is time
If this is the trend for Nike’s Revenue, a and b are the coefficients to be estimated.
The estimated trend line is R = 4.189 + 0.134t, with statistically significant coefficients.
Nike could forecast its sales in the summer quarter of 2020, which is quarter 47, as
(Figure 3.7).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.7 Nike’s Quarterly Revenue: 2009–2018
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.5 Forecasting (2 of 4)
Seasonal Variation
It appears the demand for Nike products varies seasonally.
In Figure 3.7, there is a pattern around the trend line: revenue in every summer quarter and most spring quarters is above the trend line while revenue in every fall quarter and most winter quarters is below the trend.
Seasonal variation model: R = a + b t + c1W + c2S + c3M + e
Nike’s revenue data shows a quarterly trend that is captured with seasonal dummy variables, W, S, and M.
The new estimated trend is R = 3.847 + 0.135t + 0.179W + 0.452S + 0.675M, with all coefficients statistically significant.
The forecast value for the summer quarter of 2020 is
This adjusted forecast is $340 million more than our previous forecast that ignored seasonal effects.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.5 Forecasting (3 of 4)
Nonlinear Trends
Not all time trends are linear. In particular, the revenue growth of new products is often nonlinear.
After a new product first reaches the market, its market share often grows slowly, as consumers need some time to become familiar with the product.
At some point, a successful product takes off and sales grow very rapidly.
Then, when the product eventually approaches market saturation, sales grow slowly in line with underlying population or real income growth.
Ultimately, if other products displace this product, its sales will fall sharply.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.5 Forecasting (4 of 4)
Theory-Based Econometric Forecasting
We estimated Nike’s revenue with time trend and dummy seasonal variables. However, revenue is determined in large part by the consumers’ demand curve, and the demand is affected by variables such as income, population, and advertising. Extrapolation (pure time series analysis) ignored these structural (causal) variables.
Theory-based econometric forecasting methods incorporate both extrapolation and estimation of causal or explanatory economic relationships.
We use these estimates to make conditional forecasts, where our forecast is based on specified values for the explanatory variables.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Managerial Solution
Estimating the Effect of an iTunes Price Change
How could Apple use a focus group to estimate the demand curve for iTunes to determine if raising its price would raise or lower its revenue?
Solution
To generate data, authors asked a focus group of 20 Canadian college students how many songs they would downloaded from iTunes at various prices, assuming income and other prices constant.
The estimated linear demand curve is Q = 1024 − 413p.
The t-statistic = −12.6, so this coefficient for price is significantly different from
zero. The
so the regression line fits the data closely.
Apple’s manager could use such an estimated demand curve to determine how
revenue,
varies with price. At p = 99¢, 615 songs were downloaded,
so R1 = $609. When p = $1.24, the number of songs drop to 512, R2 = $635. Revenue increased by $26.
If the general population has similar tastes to the focus group, then Apple’s revenue would increase if it raised its price to $1.24 per song.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 3.1 Data Used to Estimate the Cod Demand Curve at the Portland Fish Exchange
Price, dollars per pound | Quantity, thousand pounds per day |
1.90 | 1.5 |
1.35 | 2.2 |
1.25 | 4.4 |
1.20 | 5.9 |
0.95 | 6.5 |
0.85 | 7.0 |
0.73 | 8.8 |
0.25 | 10.1 |
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.3 Observed Price-Quantity Data Points for the Portland Fish Exchange
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 3.2 Regressions of Quantity on Advertising
Linear Specification
Blank | Coefficient | Standard Error | t-Statistic |
Constant | 5.43 | 0.54 | 10.05* |
Adverting, A | 0.53 | 0.06 | 8.47* |
Advertising, a squared | Blank | Blank | Blank |
Quadratic Specification
Coefficient | Standard Error | t-Statistic |
3.95 | 0.30 | 13.18* |
1.20 | 0.10 | 12.18* |
−0.04 | 0.01 | −7.05* |
*indicates that we can reject the null hypothesis that the coefficient is zero at the 5% significance level.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.8 iTunes Focus Group Demand and Revenue Curves
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Copyright
This work is protected by United States copyright laws and is provided solely for the use of instructors in teaching their courses and assessing student learning. Dissemination or sale of any part of this work (including on the World Wide Web) will destroy the integrity of the work and is not permitted. The work and materials from it should never be made available to students except by instructors using the accompanying text in their classes. All recipients of this work are expected to abide by these restrictions and to honor the intended pedagogical purposes and the needs of other instructors who rely on these materials.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
49
percentage change in quantity demanded
/
.(3.1)
/
percentage change in price
pp
D
e==
D
/
.
/
pp
D
e=
D
,
Q
p
(/)
D
(/)
pp
D
()
()
//
QppQ
e=
DD
/
Qp
DD
(
)
(
)
//
QppQ
¶¶
e=
0,
p
D®
/
Qp
DD
/.
Qp
¶¶
()
e<-¥
e=-¥
(/)(/)
QYYQ
DD
oo
(/)(/)
QppQ
DD
/0 and1/0
gabhb
=->=<
ˆ
ˆˆ
pghQ
=+
ˆ
ˆ
and,
gh
ˆ
,
p
ˆ
ˆ
and
gh,
ˆ
1.960.15
pQ
=-
ˆ
$0.1
¢
515
.
h
=-=-
ˆ
ˆˆ
pghQ
=+
ˆˆ
ˆˆ
=g+hQ+I
pY
ˆ
ˆ
g,h,and
î
ˆ
p
2
R
2
R
2
R
2
R
2
0.98
R
=
2
0.54
R
=
2
R
ˆ
a
,
â
2
R
2
R
27($27,000),
[53.857(1.438*27)15.031].
-=
go to FilesOptionsAdd-ins
=>=>
2
0.977,
R
=
ˆ
6,78711.414.035.179.9
YALSX
=++++
2
R
2
QabAcAe
=+++
2
0.85.
R
=
2
0.99
R
=
4.189(0.13447)$10.502 billion
+´=
3.847(0.13547)(0.1790)(0.4520)0.6751$1
(
0.84billion.
)
+´+´+´+´=
2
0.96,
R
=
(
,
)
RpQ
=´
2
A
.MsftOfcThm_Text1_Fill { fill:#000000; } .MsftOfcThm_MainDark1_Stroke { stroke:#000000; }
Managerial Economics and Strategy
Third Edition
Chapter 4
Consumer Choice
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
If this PowerPoint presentation contains mathematical equations, you may need to check that your computer has the following installed:
1) MathType Plugin
2) Math Player (free versions available)
3) NVDA Reader (free versions available)
1
Managerial Problem
Paying Employees to Relocate
How can a manager use consumer theory to optimally compensate employees who are transferred to other cities?
Solution Approach
Managers can assess the items employees consume in the original location and entice them to relocate by offering a compensation that allows them to consume basically the same in the new location. However, these packages usually overcompensate employees. To avoid costly overcompensation, managers may use the theory of consumer choice.
Empirical Methods
Individual preferences determine the satisfaction people derive from the goods and services they consume.
Consumers face constraints or limits on their choices, particularly because their budgets limit how much they can buy.
Consumers seek to maximize the level of satisfaction they obtain from consumption, subject to the constraints they face (“do the best with what they have”).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Learning Objectives (1 of 2)
4.1 Consumer Preferences
Predict consumer choices using underlying properties of consumer preferences
4.2 Utility
Summarize a consumer’s preferences using a utility function
4.3 The Budget Constraint
Explain how prices and income limit what a consumer can purchase
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Learning Objectives (2 of 2)
4.4 Constrained Consumer Choice
Show how consumers maximize their utility given prices and limited income
4.5 Deriving Demand Curves
Derive demand curves from underlying consumer preferences
4.6 Behavioral Economics
Discuss the role of behavioral biases in consumer choice
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Consumer Preferences (1 of 6)
A consumer faces choices involving many goods and must allocate his or her available budget to buy a bundle of goods.
Would ice cream or cake make a better dessert? Is it better to rent a large apartment or rent a single room and use the savings to pay for concerts?
How do consumers choose the bundles of goods they buy?
One possibility is that consumers behave randomly and blindly choose one good or another without any thought.
Another is that they make systematic choices.
To explain consumer behavior, economists assume that consumers have a set of tastes or preferences that they use to guide them in choosing between goods.
These tastes differ substantially among individuals. For example, three out of four European men prefer colored underwear, while three out of four American men prefer white underwear.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Consumer Preferences (2 of 6)
Properties of Consumer Preferences
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Consumer Preferences (3 of 6)
Properties of Consumer Preferences
Completeness
When a consumer faces a choice between any two bundles of goods, only one of the following is true. The consumer might prefer the first bundle to the second, or the second bundle to the first, or be indifferent between the two bundles. Indifference is allowed, but indecision is not.
Transitivity
If a is strictly preferred to b and b is strictly preferred to c, it follows that a must be strictly preferred to c. Transitivity applies also to weak preference and indifference relationships.
More is better
All else being the same, more of a good is better than less. This is a nonsatiation property.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Consumer Preferences (4 of 6)
Preference Maps
A preference map is a complete set of indifference curves that summarize a consumer’s tastes.
An indifference curve is the set of all bundles of goods that a consumer views as being equally desirable.
Panel c of Figure 4.1 shows three of Lisa’s indifference curves:
In this figure, the indifference curves are parallel, but they need not be.
Preferences and Indifference Curves
Bundles on indifference curves farther from the origin are preferred to those on indifference curves closer to the origin.
There is an indifference curve through every possible bundle.
Indifference curves cannot cross.
Indifference curves slope downward.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.1 Bundles of Pizzas and Burritos That Lisa Might Consume
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Consumer Preferences (5 of 6)
Willingness to Substitute Between Goods
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Consumer Preferences (6 of 6)
Willingness to Substitute Between Goods
The Marginal Rate of Substitution (M R S) is the rate at which a consumer can substitute one good for another while remaining on the same indifference curve.
If pizza is on the horizontal axis in Figure 4.3 (a), Lisa’s marginal rate of substitution of burritos for pizza is M R S = ΔB/ΔZ, where ΔB is the number of burritos Lisa will give up to get ΔZ more pizzas while staying on the same indifference curve.
The indifference curves in Figure 4.3 (a) are convex or “bowed in” toward the origin. This willingness to trade fewer burritos for one more pizza reflects a diminishing marginal rate of substitution.
Curvature of Indifference Curves
Convex indifference curves reflect imperfect substitutes (panel a in Figure 4.3 and panel c in Figure 4.4).
Straight-line indifference curves reflect perfect substitutes, goods that are essentially equivalent for the consumer (Panel a, Figure 4.4).
Right-angle indifference curves reflect perfect complements, goods consumed only in fixed proportions (Panel b, Figure 4.4).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.3 Marginal Rate of Substitution
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.4 Perfect Substitutes, Perfect Complements, and Imperfect Substitutes
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.2 Utility (1 of 2)
Utility Functions
Our consumer behavior model assumes that consumers can compare bundles of goods and take the one with the greatest satisfaction.
If we knew the utility function—the relationship between utility measures and every possible bundle of goods—we could summarize the information in indifference
maps succinctly. Lisa’s utility function
Utility functions do not exist in any fundamental sense.
If you ask your mother what her utility function is, she would be puzzled. However, she could easily answer: “Do you want one scoop of ice cream with two pieces of cake or two scoops of ice cream with one piece of cake?” Also, she may not know how much more she prefers one bundle to the other.
Ordinal and Cardinal Utility
Ordinal utility if we know only a consumer’s relative rankings of bundles.
Cardinal utility if we know absolute numerical comparisons.
Most of our discussion of consumer choice in this chapter holds if utility has only ordinal properties. We care only about the relative utility or ranking of the two bundles.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.2 Utility (2 of 2)
Marginal Utility (M U)
Marginal utility is the slope of the utility function as we hold the quantity of the
other good constant,
Given Lisa’s utility function
Lisa’s marginal utility from
increasing her consumption of pizza from 4 to 5 in Figure 4.5 is
Using calculus: If
Marginal Rates of Substitution (M R S)
The M R S depends on the negative of the ratio of the marginal utility of one good to the marginal utility of another good.
Lisa’s M R S depends on the negative of the ratio of the M U of pizza to
the M U of burritos,
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.5 Utility and Marginal Utility
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 The Budget Constraint (1 of 3)
Consumers maximize their well-being subject to constraints, and the most important is the budget constraint.
The budget constraint or budget line shows the bundles of goods that can be bought if the entire budget is spent on those goods at given prices.
In Figure 4.6, Lisa’s budget constraint is p B B + p Z Z = Y, where p B B and p Z Z are the amounts she spends on burritos and pizzas.
How many burritos can Liza buy?
Lisa can afford to buy more burritos B only if her income Y increases, the prices of burritos and pizza (p B, p Z) falls, or she buys fewer pizzas Z.
In Figure 4.6, p B = $2, p Z =$1, Y = $50. So,
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 The Budget Constraint (2 of 3)
The opportunity set is all the bundles a consumer can buy, including all the bundles inside the budget constraint and on the budget constraint.
In Figure 4.6, the opportunity set is all those bundles of positive Z
and B such that
Slope of the Budget Line
It is determined by the relative prices of the two goods and is called the
marginal rate of transformation
In Figure 4.6, Lisa’s
She can “trade” an extra pizza
for half a burrito or give up two pizzas to obtain an extra burrito.
Using calculus, If
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.6 The Budget Line
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 The Budget Constraint (3 of 3)
Effects of a Change in Price on the Opportunity Set
If the price of pizza doubles but the price of burritos is unchanged, the budget line swings in toward the origin (Figure 4.7a).
The new budget line is steeper and lies inside the original one. Unless Lisa only wants to eat burritos, she is unambiguously worse off, she can no longer afford the combinations of pizza and burritos in the shaded “Loss” area.
Effects of a Change in Income on the Opportunity Set
If the consumer’s income increases, the consumer can buy more of all goods.
A change in income affects only the position and not the slope of the budget line.
If Lisa’s income increases and relative prices do not change, her budget line shifts outward (away from the origin) and is parallel to the original constraint (Figure 4.7b)
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.7 Changes in the Budget Line
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.4 Constrained Consumer Choice (1 of 4)
The Consumer’s Optimal Bundle
The optimal bundle must lie on an indifference curve that touches the budget line but does not cross it.
So, M R S = M R T
For the case of Lisa that only consumes pizza Z and burritos B,
M R S = M R T becomes
Rearranging terms,
In words, the marginal utility per dollar spent on pizza is equal to the marginal utility per dollar spent on burritos.
Thus, Lisa maximizes her utility if the last dollar she spends on pizza gets her as much extra utility as the last dollar she spends on burritos. If the last dollar spent on pizza gave Lisa more extra utility than the last dollar spent on burritos, Lisa could increase her happiness by spending more on pizza and less on burritos.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.4 Constrained Consumer Choice (2 of 4)
There are two ways to reach an optimal bundle, interior and corner solutions.
Interior Solutions
An interior solution occurs when the optimal bundle has positive quantities of both goods and lies between the ends of the budget line.
In Figure 4.8, bundle e with 30 pizzas and 10 burritos per
semester is on indifference curve
It is an optimum interior
solution.
Corner Solutions
A corner solution occurs when the optimal bundle is at one end of the budget line, where the budget line forms a corner with one of the axes.
In Figure 4.9, bundle e with 0 pizzas and 25 burritos per semester
is on indifference curve
It is an optimum corner solution.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.8 Consumer Maximization, Interior Solution
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.9 Consumer Maximization, Corner Solution
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.4 Constrained Consumer Choice (3 of 4)
Promotions
Managers induce consumers to buy more units with promotions. The two most used are buy one, get one free (B O G O) and buy one, get the second at a half price.
Buy One, Get One Free (B O G O)
The B O G O promotion creates a kink in the budget line and its acceptance depends on the shape of the indifference curves.
In Figure 4.10, with the B O G O promotion “buy 3 nights, get the 4th free” the new
budget line is
for both Angela and Betty.
In panel a, without the promotion, Angela’s indifference curve
is tangent to
at point x, so she chooses to spend two nights at the resort. With the B O G O
promotion, her indifference curve
cuts the new budget line
There’s a higher
indifference curve,
that touches
at point y, where she chooses to stay four
nights.
In panel b, without the promotion, Betty chooses to stay two nights at x where her
indifference curve
does not cut the new budget line
no higher indifference curve can touch
so Betty stays only two nights, at x,
and does not take advantage of the B O G O promotion.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.10 B O G O Promotions
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.4 Constrained Consumer Choice (4 of 4)
Managerial Implication: Designing Promotions
When deciding whether to use a B O G O promotion, a manager should compare the benefit to the cost.
For example, offering such a promotion is more likely to raise the hotel’s profit if it has excess capacity, so that the cost of providing a room for an extra night’s stay is very low.
To design an effective promotion, a manager should use experiments to learn about customers’ preferences.
For example, a manager could offer each promotion for a short period and keep track of how many customers respond to each promotion, how many nights they choose to stay, and by how much the promotion increases the firm’s profit.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.5 Deriving Demand Curves
We use consumer theory to show how much the quantity demanded of a good falls as its price rises.
An individual chooses an optimal bundle of goods by picking the point on the highest indifference curve that touches the budget line.
In panel a of Figure 4.11 , e1 is the highest indifference curve that touches
A change in price causes the budget line to rotate, so that the consumer chooses a new optimal bundle.
In panel a of Figure 4.11, a price change from £2 to £1 makes the budget line to
rotate from
The new optimal bundle is e2.
By varying one price and holding other prices and income constant, we determine how the quantity demanded changes as the price changes, which is the information we need to draw the demand curve.
In panel b of Figure 4.11, E1, E2, and E3 are the points of the demand curve derived from price changes, budget lines, and indifference curves in panel a.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.11 Deriving an Individual’s Demand Curve
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.6 Behavioral Economics (1 of 3)
So far, we have assumed that consumers are rational, maximizing individuals.
Behavioral economics adds insights from psychology and empirical research on human cognitive and emotional biases to the rational economic model to better predict economic decision making.
We discuss three applications of behavioral economics: tests of transitivity, endowment effects, and salience.
Tests of Transitivity
It is appropriate to assume that adults exhibit transitivity for most economic decisions. But, it is not appropriate for children or when novel goods are introduced.
Some argue that children need some form of protection because they lack of transitivity to maximize their well-being.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.6 Behavioral Economics (2 of 3)
Endowment Effects
People place a higher value on a good if they own it than they do if they are considering buying it.
One implication of the endowment effect is that consumer’s behavior may differ depending on how a choice is posed.
However, the common belief (common confusion) is that people respond the same way to equivalent questions.
Salience
People are more likely to consider information if it is presented in a way that grabs their attention or if it takes relatively little thought or calculation to understand.
If tax requires calculations, buyers may just ignored it because of costly calculations (bounded rationality).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.6 Behavioral Economics (3 of 3)
Managerial Implication: Simplifying Consumer Choices
Today’s consumers often feel overwhelmed by choices, for instance, hundreds of channels in Cable T V subscriptions. Because consumers have bounded rationality, most dislike considering all the possibilities and making decisions. At the end, many consumers do not buy these services just to avoid this problem.
Good managers can make decision making easier for consumers. They may offer default bundles so consumers don’t have to make difficult decisions.
For example, Cable T V companies package groups of channels by content, sports, or movie packages. Rather than thinking through each option, the customer can make a much easier decision, such as “I like sports” or “I like movies,” and is more likely to make a purchase.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Managerial Solution
Paying Employees to Relocate
How can a manager use consumer theory to optimally compensate employees who are transferred to other cities?
Solution
Managers collect information about the cost of living in various cities. They know that it is more expensive to buy the same bundle of goods in one city than another and that relative prices differ across cities.
Typical relocation: Alex’s firm wants to transfer him from Seattle to London, where he will face different prices and cost of living. Alex spends his money on housing and entertainment and gets a bundle s that maximizes his satisfaction in Seattle. The firm offers him enough money to buy bundle s in London.
Alex may be better off: entertainment is relatively cheaper in London, but Alex is paid enough to buy bundle s. So, he can substitute housing with entertainment and reach a higher indifference curve.
The firm may offer him less income: There is a lower budget constraint that can put Alex in London at the same indifference curve as in Seattle with less income than the previous solution.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.2 Impossible Indifference Curves
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 4.1 Allocations of a $50 Budget Between Burritos and Pizza
Bundle | Burritos, $2 each | Pizza, $1 each |
a | 25 | 0 |
b | 20 | 10 |
c | 10 | 30 |
d | 0 | 50 |
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Copyright
This work is protected by United States copyright laws and is provided solely for the use of instructors in teaching their courses and assessing student learning. Dissemination or sale of any part of this work (including on the World Wide Web) will destroy the integrity of the work and is not permitted. The work and materials from it should never be made available to students except by instructors using the accompanying text in their classes. All recipients of this work are expected to abide by these restrictions and to honor the intended pedagogical purposes and the needs of other instructors who rely on these materials.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
37
123
,, and .
III
()
UB,Z
BZ
=
/.
Z
MUUZ
=DD
()
, 1,,
)
0
(
=
UBZUZ
/ 20/1 20.
Z
MUUZ
=DD==
,, the
()
n ,
)
(
/.
Z
UBZMUUBZZ
=¶¶
/.
ZB
MRSMUMU
=-
Z
BB
p
Y
BZ
pp
=-
1
25 .
2
BZ
=-
.
BZ
pBpZY
+£
(
.
)
/
ZB
pp
=-
MRT
1/2.
=-
MRT
, then d/d/.
Z
ZB
BB
p
Y
BZBZpp
pp
=-==-
MRT
//.
ZBZB
MUMUpp
-=-
//.
=
ZZBB
MUpMUp
2
.
I
2
L
1
l
1
L
1
l
2
.
L
2
,
l
313
is tangent to . Because
ILI
2
,
L
2
,
L
1
L.
12
L to L.
.MsftOfcThm_Text1_Fill { fill:#000000; } .MsftOfcThm_MainDark1_Stroke { stroke:#000000; }

Get help from top-rated tutors in any subject.
Efficiently complete your homework and academic assignments by getting help from the experts at homeworkarchive.com